81 FR 30550 - United States v. Charter Communications, Inc., et al.; Proposed Final Judgment and Competitive Impact Statement

DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE
Antitrust Division

Federal Register Volume 81, Issue 95 (May 17, 2016)

Page Range30550-30565
FR Document2016-11562

Federal Register, Volume 81 Issue 95 (Tuesday, May 17, 2016)
[Federal Register Volume 81, Number 95 (Tuesday, May 17, 2016)]
[Notices]
[Pages 30550-30565]
From the Federal Register Online  [www.thefederalregister.org]
[FR Doc No: 2016-11562]


=======================================================================
-----------------------------------------------------------------------

DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE

Antitrust Division


United States v. Charter Communications, Inc., et al.; Proposed 
Final Judgment and Competitive Impact Statement

    Notice is hereby given pursuant to the Antitrust Procedures and 
Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16(b)-(h), that a proposed Final Judgment, 
Stipulation, and Competitive Impact Statement have been filed with the 
United States District Court for the District of Columbia in United 
States of America v. Charter Communications, Inc., et al., Civil Action 
No. 16-cv-00759. On April 25, 2016, the United States filed a Complaint 
alleging that Charter Communications, Inc.'s proposed acquisitions of 
Time Warner Cable Inc. and Bright House Networks, LLC would violate 
Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. The proposed Final 
Judgment, filed at the same time as the Complaint, forbids the merged 
company from engaging in certain conduct that could make it more 
difficult for competing online video distributors (OVDs) to obtain 
programming content.
    Copies of the Complaint, proposed Final Judgment, and Competitive 
Impact Statement are available for inspection on the Antitrust 
Division's Web site at http://www.justice.gov/atr and at the Office of 
the Clerk of the United States District Court for the District of 
Columbia. Copies of these materials may be obtained from the Antitrust 
Division upon request and payment of the copying fee set by Department 
of Justice regulations.
    Public comment is invited within 60 days of the date of this 
notice. Such comments, including the name of the submitter, and 
responses thereto, will be posted on the Antitrust Division's Web site, 
filed with the Court, and, under certain circumstances, published in 
the Federal Register. Comments should be directed to Scott A. Scheele, 
Chief, Telecommunications and Media Enforcement Section, Antitrust 
Division, Department of Justice, 450 Fifth Street NW., Suite 7000, 
Washington, DC 20530 (telephone: 202-616-5924).

Patricia A. Brink,
Director of Civil Enforcement.

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA

    United States of America, Department of Justice, Antitrust 
Division, 450 5th Street N.W., Suite 7000, Washington, DC, 20530, 
Plaintiff, v., Charter Communications, Inc., 400 Atlantic Street, 
Stamford, CT 06901, Time Warner Cable Inc., 60 Columbus Circle, New 
York, NY 10023, Advance/Newhouse Partnership, 5823 Widewaters 
Parkway, East Syracuse, NY 13057, and, Bright House Networks, LLC, 
5823 Widewaters Parkway, East Syracuse, NY 13057, Defendants.

Case No.: 1:16-cv-00759
Judge: Royce C. Lamberth
Filed: 04/25/2016

[[Page 30551]]

COMPLAINT

    The United States of America, acting under the direction of the 
Attorney General of the United States, brings this civil antitrust 
action to enjoin the proposed combination of Charter Communications, 
Inc. (``Charter''), Time Warner Cable Inc. (``TWC''), and Advance/
Newhouse Partnership's (``Advance/Newhouse'') subsidiary, Bright House 
Networks, LLC (``BHN'') (collectively referred to herein as ``New 
Charter''), which would create the second-largest cable company and the 
third-largest multi-channel video distributor in the United States.

I. INTRODUCTION

    1. Online video programming distributors (``OVDs'') are beginning 
to revolutionize the way Americans receive and experience video 
content. With access to an adequate Internet connection, consumers can 
now choose among a number of OVDs to access collections of movies and 
television shows, including original content, at any time and on a 
device of their choosing. The early OVDs, such as Netflix, Hulu, and 
Amazon, focused on offering on-demand video to their customers and have 
developed video services that have already proven popular. Several 
newer OVDs, including DISH Network's Sling TV and Sony's Playstation 
Vue, have introduced services that offer live television channels in 
addition to on-demand content. And several television networks, 
including CBS, HBO, and Showtime, have launched OVD services to 
distribute their own programming over the Internet directly to 
subscribers. Continued growth of OVDs promises to deliver more 
competitive choices and a greater ability for consumers to customize 
their consumption of video content to their individual viewing 
preferences and budgets.
    2. The emergence of OVDs threatens to upend the competitive 
landscape. For years, incumbent cable companies such as Comcast, TWC, 
and Charter have served the majority of American video households. 
Although these companies now face competition from the two direct 
broadcast satellite (``DBS'') providers, DirecTV and DISH Network, and, 
in some areas, from telephone companies (``telcos'') like AT&T and 
Verizon that also offer video services, all of these distributors--
collectively referred to as multichannel video programming distributors 
(``MVPDs'')--offer fairly similar products and pricing. Most notably, 
all of these MVPDs sell content to consumers primarily through large 
and costly video bundles that include hundreds of channels of 
programming that many customers neither desire nor watch.
    3. In order for an OVD to successfully compete with the traditional 
MVPDs, it needs both the ability to reach consumers over the Internet 
and the ability to obtain programming from content providers that 
consumers will want to watch. Importantly, incumbent cable companies 
often can exert significant influence over one or both of these 
essential ingredients to an OVD's success, because they provide 
broadband connectivity that OVDs need to reach consumers and are also a 
critical distribution channel for the same video programmers that 
supply OVDs with video content. To the extent a transaction, such as 
the one at issue here, enhances an MVPD's ability or incentive to 
restrain OVDs' access to either of these critical inputs, and thus to 
prevent OVDs from becoming a meaningful new competitive option, 
consumers lose.
    4. MVPDs have responded to the emergence of OVDs in various ways. 
Many MVPDs have sought to keep their customers from migrating some or 
all of their viewing to OVDs by taking steps to make their services 
more attractive to consumers, for example, by allowing their 
subscribers to receive programming over the Internet through Web sites 
or apps and providing expanded video-on-demand offerings. But some 
MVPDs have sought to restrain nascent OVD competition directly by 
exercising their leverage over video programmers to restrict the 
programmers' ability to license content to OVDs. To this end, some 
MVPDs have sought so-called Alternative Distribution Means (``ADM'') 
clauses in their programming contracts that prohibit programmers from 
distributing content online, or have placed significant restrictions on 
online distribution. No MVPD has sought and obtained these restrictive 
ADMs as frequently, or as successfully, as TWC.
    5. The combination of TWC with Charter and BHN will result in a 
larger MVPD with a greater ability and incentive to secure restrictions 
on programmers that limit or foreclose OVD access to important content. 
The Defendants, along with other MVPDs and OVDs, compete with one 
another as buyers of video content and serve as alternative 
distribution channels for national video programmers to build 
viewership scale. Since New Charter would have nearly 60 percent more 
subscribers than TWC standing alone, the merger will make New Charter a 
more vital distribution channel for these video programmers than each 
of the Defendants individually. Hence, as a result of the merger, New 
Charter will have greater bargaining leverage to insist that video 
programmers limit their distribution to OVDs.
    6. In addition, with its much larger subscriber base, New Charter 
would gain significant additional benefits from impeding OVD 
competition. Today, Charter, TWC, and BHN each only act to protect its 
own MVPD profits. After the merger, however, New Charter would act to 
protect the much larger combined video revenues of all three 
Defendants. That is, while prior to the merger TWC has an incentive to 
obtain restrictive contract clauses to protect its $10.4 billion in 
video revenues, New Charter would have a much larger incentive to 
protect the Defendants' over $16 billion in aggregated video revenues.
    7. With more to gain from imposing ADMs and other contractual 
restrictions and with greater bargaining leverage with programmers to 
insist on such provisions, New Charter will be well-positioned to 
restrain continued OVD growth by limiting or foreclosing OVD access to 
the video content that is vital to their competitiveness. Accordingly, 
the proposed combination of Charter, TWC, and BHN is likely to 
substantially lessen competition in the provision of video programming 
distribution in violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 
18, and should be enjoined.

II. JURISDICTION AND VENUE

    8. The United States brings this action under Section 15 of the 
Clayton Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C. 25, to prevent and restrain Charter, 
TWC, and BHN from violating Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18.
    9. Defendants Charter, TWC, and BHN all provide video distribution 
services to programmers in the flow of interstate commerce, 
distributing video programming to millions of consumers in numerous 
states within the United States. Accordingly, Defendants' activities 
substantially affect interstate commerce. The Court has subject matter 
jurisdiction over this action and these Defendants pursuant to Section 
15 of the Clayton Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C. 25, and 28 U.S.C. 1331, 
1337(a), and 1345.
    10. Defendants have consented to personal jurisdiction and venue in 
the District of Columbia for the purposes of this action.

III. THE PARTIES AND THE PROPOSED TRANSACTION

    11. Defendant Charter is a Delaware corporation with headquarters 
in

[[Page 30552]]

Stamford, Connecticut. With over 4.2 million video subscribers across 
28 states, Charter is the third-largest cable company in the United 
States (behind Comcast and TWC) and the sixth-largest MVPD in the 
nation. In 2014, Charter reported total revenues of around $9.1 
billion. Nearly 49% of those revenues, around $4.4 billion, were 
derived from Charter's video business.
    12. Defendant TWC is a New York corporation with headquarters in 
New York, New York. With over 10.8 million video subscribers across 30 
states, TWC is the second-largest cable company in the United States 
(behind only Comcast), and the fourth-largest MVPD in the country. In 
2014, TWC reported total revenues of approximately $22.8 billion. 
Around 45% of those revenues, or about $10.4 billion, were derived from 
TWC's video business.
    13. Defendant Advance/Newhouse is a New York partnership with 
headquarters in East Syracuse, New York, and the sole owner of 
Defendant BHN, a Delaware limited liability company headquartered in 
East Syracuse, New York. BHN is the sixth-largest cable company in the 
United States and the ninth-largest MVPD. BHN owns cable systems 
serving around 2 million video customers across six states. In 2014, 
BHN generated total revenues of around $3.7 billion, approximately $1.5 
billion of which were derived from its video business.
    14. On May 23, 2015, Charter, TWC, and Advance/Newhouse entered 
into a series of agreements that would combine Charter, TWC, and BHN 
into a single company, New Charter. Pursuant to these agreements, (1) 
Charter and TWC would merge in a transaction valued at over $78 
billion; and (2) Charter would acquire BHN from Advance/Newhouse in a 
transaction valued at $10.4 billion. The combined entity would have 
nearly 17.4 million video subscribers across 41 states, making it the 
second-largest cable company and third-largest MVPD, accounting for 
nearly 18% of all MVPD subscribers in the United States.

IV. THE VIDEO PROGRAMMING DISTRIBUTION INDUSTRY

    15. There are two distinct levels to the video programming 
distribution industry. At the ``upstream'' level, video programmers 
license their content to video programming distributors--both OVDs and 
traditional MVPDs including Charter, TWC, and BHN. At the 
``downstream'' level, the video programming distributors then sell 
subscriptions to various packages of that content and deliver the 
content to residential customers.
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17MY16.332

    16. Video programmers produce themselves, or acquire from other 
copyright holders, a collection of professional, full-length programs 
and movies. These video programmers then typically aggregate this 
content into branded networks (e.g., NBC, ESPN, or The History Channel) 
to create a 24-hour-per-day television service that is attractive to 
consumers. Many of the largest video programmers control the rights to 
multiple networks. Except for networks of purely local or regional 
interest, the video programmers will contract with video programming 
distributors across the country to distribute the content to consumers.
    17. In order to acquire the rights to distribute each network, 
video programming distributors pay the video programmer a license fee. 
Generally, MVPDs and OVDs pay the video programmer a monthly per-
subscriber fee. These license fees are an important revenue stream for 
video programmers. Most of the remainder of their revenues comes from 
fees for advertisements placed on their networks.
    18. Video programmers rely on video programming distributors to 
reach consumers. Unless a video programmer obtains carriage in the 
packages of video programming distributors that reach a sufficient 
number of consumers, the programmers will be unable to earn enough 
revenue in licensing or to attract enough advertising revenue to 
generate a return on their investments in content. For this reason, 
video programmers prefer to have as many video programming distributors 
as possible carry their networks, and particularly seek out the largest 
MVPDs that reach the most customers. If the programmer is unable to 
agree on acceptable terms with a particular distributor, the 
programmer's content will not be available to that distributor's 
customers. This potential consequence gives the largest MVPDs 
significant bargaining leverage in their negotiations with programmers.

V. RELEVANT MARKET

    19. The timely distribution of professional, full-length video 
programming to residential customers (``video programming 
distribution'') constitutes a relevant product market and line of 
commerce under Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. Both

[[Page 30553]]

MVPDs and OVDs are participants in this market.
    20. Video programming distribution is characterized by the 
aggregation and delivery of professionally produced content. This 
content includes scripted and unscripted television shows, live 
programming, sports, news, and movies licensed from a mixture of 
broadcast and cable networks, as well as from movie studios. Video 
programming can be viewed immediately by consumers, whether on demand 
or as scheduled.
    21. Consumers purchase video programming distribution services from 
among those distributors that can offer such services directly to their 
home. The DBS operators, DirecTV and DISH, can reach almost any 
customer in the continental United States who has an unobstructed line 
of sight to their satellites. OVDs are available to any consumer with 
Internet service sufficient to deliver video of an acceptable quality. 
In contrast, wireline-based distributors such as cable companies and 
telcos generally must obtain a franchise from local, municipal, or 
state authorities in order to construct and operate a wireline network 
in a specific area, and then build lines to homes in that area. A 
consumer cannot purchase video programming distribution services from a 
wireline distributor operating outside its franchise area because the 
distributor does not have the facilities to reach the consumer's home. 
Thus, although the set of video programming distributors able to offer 
service to individual consumers' residences is generally the same 
within each local community, the set can differ from one local 
community to another.
    22. Each local community whose residents face the same competitive 
choices in video programming distribution comprises a local geographic 
market and section of the country under Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 
15 U.S.C. 18. A hypothetical monopolist of video programming 
distribution in any of these geographic areas could profitably raise 
prices by a small but significant, non-transitory amount.
    23. The specific geographic markets relevant to this action are the 
numerous local markets throughout the United States shown in the map 
below where either Charter, TWC, or BHN is the incumbent cable 
operator.
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17MY16.333

In order to protect its profits in these geographic markets, which 
cover around 48 million U.S. television households across 41 states, 
New Charter will have an incentive to prevent rival OVDs from 
obtaining, or to raise the costs of those rivals obtaining, programming 
for their services. Because these OVD competitors also serve homes 
outside New Charter's service areas, however, other local markets may 
be affected, with the anticompetitive effects of the transaction likely 
extending to the whole nation.

VI. MARKET CONCENTRATION

    24. The incumbent cable companies typically have the highest share 
of subscribers within their respective service areas, often above 50 
percent. The DBS providers, DirecTV and DISH, account for approximately 
one-third of the video programming distribution subscribers nationwide, 
although their shares vary by local market. The telcos, AT&T and 
Verizon, account for over 10 percent of video programming distribution 
nationwide and have successfully achieved penetration of up to 40 
percent in some areas, but their video services remain limited to 
certain local markets and are unavailable to most American homes. In a 
handful of areas, other providers called ``overbuilders'' have 
constructed an additional wireline network to residential consumers, 
offering another competitive option for video and broadband service. 
But these overbuilders, including companies like RCN and Google Fiber, 
are available in very few communities, serving less than two percent of 
U.S. television households nationwide.
    25. Although OVDs have acquired a significant number of customers 
over the last several years, they account for only five percent of 
total video programming distribution revenues. Nevertheless, 
established distributors such as Charter, TWC, and BHN view OVDs as a 
growing competitive threat and have taken steps to respond to OVD 
entry.

[[Page 30554]]

VII. ANTICOMPETITIVE EFFECTS

    26. Charter, TWC, and BHN compete with DBS, overbuilder, and telco 
providers by upgrading their existing services, offering promotions and 
other price discounts, and introducing new product offerings. Consumers 
benefit from this competition by receiving better quality services, 
lower prices, and more programming choices. Competition between the 
incumbent cable companies and these alternative video providers has 
also fostered innovation, including the development of digital 
transmission, HD, and 4K programming, and the introduction of DVRs, 
video-on-demand, and ways to view content on other devices or away from 
home.
    27. The continued development and expansion of OVDs could unlock 
additional competitive benefits. Today, many consumers purchase OVD 
services as a supplement to a traditional MVPD subscription. But in 
light of expanding OVD options, some consumers are switching from 
larger, more expensive MVPD bundles to slimmer and cheaper bundles. A 
small number of consumers are even ``cutting the cord''--cancelling 
their MVPD subscription altogether and relying solely on one or more 
OVDs to receive content. And many younger consumers are emerging as 
``cord nevers'' that do not seek out an MVPD subscription in the first 
place. Large cable companies such as Charter and TWC, which rely on 
their video businesses to deliver significant profit margins, have 
observed these developments with growing concern. In numerous internal 
documents, Defendants show a keen awareness of the competitive threat 
that OVDs pose. In fact, a TWC board presentation from February 2014 
illustrated the threat posed by such emerging online competitors as a 
meteor speeding toward earth:
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17MY16.334

    28. Because of the threat OVDs pose to their video business, some 
MVPDs have an incentive to engage in tactics that would diminish OVDs' 
ability to compete. TWC, in particular, has recognized that it can use 
its contracts with video programmers to try and foreclose OVD 
competitors from access to valuable content. TWC has been the most 
aggressive MVPD in the industry in seeking and obtaining restrictive 
contract provisions in its agreements with programmers that limit the 
programmer's ability to license programming to OVDs. Specifically, TWC 
has used the leverage that comes from its status as an important 
distribution channel for many video programmers to secure ADM 
provisions that either prevent the programmer from distributing its 
content online, or place certain restrictions on such online 
distribution. For example, some of TWC's ADMs prohibit any online 
distribution for a certain period of time; others prevent the 
programmers from distributing their content through OVDs that do not 
meet specific criteria that can be difficult for OVDs to satisfy (e.g., 
requiring the OVD to include a minimum number of programming networks 
in its service).
    29. Although they offer service to residential customers in 
different local areas, each of the Defendants serves as an alternative 
distribution channel for nationwide video programmers to deliver their 
content to consumers and to build national viewership scale. Video 
programmers rely on traditional MVPDs to provide licensing fees and to 
build a large viewership base that is attractive to advertisers. Post-
merger, New Charter will become one of the largest MVPDs in the country 
and will serve as a critical distributor for video programmers, 
offering access to over 17 million customers spread across 41 states. 
As a result, New Charter will have more leverage to demand that video 
programmers agree to forego or limit the licensing of programming to 
OVDs.
    30. In addition, New Charter will have greater incentive to engage 
in conduct designed to make OVDs less competitive because the merged 
firm will be significantly larger than any of the Defendants 
individually. Because New Charter will have far more subscribers, it 
will also stand to lose more profits as OVDs continue to take business 
from traditional video distributors. Today,

[[Page 30555]]

any conduct that Charter engages in to harm OVDs would only benefit 
Charter within its own service territory. After the merger, New Charter 
will internalize the combined benefits to Charter, TWC, and BHN of 
harming OVDs and therefore will have a greater incentive to do so, and 
will be willing to offer more consideration to video programmers to 
obtain licensing restrictions.
    31. Restrictions imposed on video programmers by New Charter will 
likely make it more difficult for OVDs to obtain important content from 
programmers in the future. In order to comply with New Charter's 
restrictions, video programmers may have to effectively cease providing 
certain programming to an OVD altogether, or may be obligated to impose 
burdensome conditions on an OVD (such as the requirement to include a 
minimum number of programming networks in the service). Such actions 
could negatively affect OVDs' business models and undermine their 
ability to provide robust video offerings that compete with the 
offerings of traditional MVPDs. By limiting OVDs' access to content 
that is important to their customers, the competitiveness of OVDs will 
likely be diminished and consumers will likely receive lower-quality 
services and fewer choices.

VIII. ENTRY

    32. Entry or expansion of traditional video programming 
distributors will not be timely, likely, or sufficient to reverse the 
competitive harm that would likely result from the proposed merger of 
Charter, TWC, and BHN. Entry and expansion in the traditional video 
programming distribution business is difficult and time-consuming 
because it requires an enormous upfront investment to create 
distribution infrastructure such as building out wireline facilities or 
launching satellites. Entry or expansion into a new geographic area 
also typically requires approval from one or more regulatory bodies.
    33. OVDs are less likely to enter or expand to develop into 
significant competitors if denied access to popular content as a result 
of the proposed transaction.

IX. VIOLATION ALLEGED

    34. The United States hereby incorporates paragraphs 1 through 33.
    35. Defendants' proposed combination of Charter, TWC, and BHN would 
likely substantially lessen competition in the numerous geographic 
markets for video programming distribution identified above in 
violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18.
    36. Unless enjoined, the proposed transactions between Charter, 
TWC, and Advance/Newhouse would likely have the following 
anticompetitive effects, among others:
    a. competition in the development, provision, and sale of video 
programming distribution services in each of the relevant geographic 
markets will likely be substantially lessened;
    b. prices for video programming distribution services will likely 
increase to levels above those that would prevail absent the proposed 
transactions; and
    c. innovation and quality of video programming distribution 
services will likely decrease to levels below those that would prevail 
absent the proposed transactions.

X. REQUESTED RELIEF

    37. Plaintiff United States requests that this Court:
    a. adjudge and decree that the proposed transactions violate 
Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18;
    b. preliminarily and permanently enjoin the Defendants from 
carrying out the proposed transactions, or from entering into or 
carrying out any other agreement, understanding, or plan that would 
have the effect of bringing the video distribution businesses of 
Charter, TWC, and BHN under common ownership or control;
    c. award the United States its costs in this action; and
    d. award the United States such other and further relief as may be 
just and proper.

Dated: April 25, 2016.

Respectfully submitted,

For Plaintiff United States of America:

/s/--------------------------------------------------------------------

Renata B. Hesse (D.C. Bar #466107).

Principal Deputy Assistant Attorney General.

/s/--------------------------------------------------------------------

Patricia A. Brink,
Director of Civil Enforcement.

/s/--------------------------------------------------------------------

Scott A. Scheele (D.C. Bar #429061),
Chief, Telecommunications & Media Enforcement Section.

/s/--------------------------------------------------------------------

Lawrence M. Frankel (D.C. Bar #441532),
Assistant Chief, Telecommunications & Media Enforcement Section.

/s/--------------------------------------------------------------------

Robert A. Lepore*,
Ruediger R. Schuett (D.C. Bar #501174),
Maureen Casey (D.C. Bar #415893),

Trial Attorneys, U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division, 
Telecommunications & Media Enforcement Section, 450 Fifth Street 
NW., Suite 7000, Washington, DC 20530, Telephone: (202) 532-4928, 
Facsimile: (202) 514-6381, Email: [email protected], *Attorney 
of Record

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA

    United States of America, Plaintiff, v. Charter Communications, 
Inc., Time Warner Cable Inc, Advance/Newhouse Partnership, and 
Bright House Networks, LLC, Defendants.

Case No.: 1:16-cv-00759
Judge: Royce C. Lamberth
Filed: 05/10/2016

COMPETITIVE IMPACT STATEMENT

    The United States of America (``United States''), pursuant to 
Section 2(b) of the Antitrust Procedures and Penalties Act (``APPA'' or 
``Tunney Act''), 15 U.S.C. 16(b)-(h), files this Competitive Impact 
Statement relating to the proposed Final Judgment submitted for entry 
in this civil antitrust proceeding.

I. NATURE AND PURPOSE OF THE PROCEEDING

    On May 23, 2015, Charter Communications, Inc. (``Charter'') and 
Time Warner Cable, Inc. (``TWC''), two of the largest cable companies 
in the United States, agreed to merge in a deal valued at over $78 
billion. In addition, Charter and Advance/Newhouse Partnership, which 
owns Bright House Networks, LLC (``BHN''), announced that Charter would 
acquire BHN for $10.4 billion, conditional on the sale of TWC to 
Charter. As a result of these transactions, the combined company, 
referred to as ``New Charter,'' will become one of the largest 
providers of pay television service in the United States.
    The United States filed a civil antitrust Complaint on April 25, 
2016, seeking to enjoin the proposed transactions because their likely 
effect would be to lessen competition substantially in numerous local 
markets for the timely distribution of professional, full-length video 
programming to residential customers (``video programming 
distribution'') throughout the United States in violation of Section 7 
of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. Specifically, the Complaint alleges 
that the proposed merger would increase the ability and incentive of 
New Charter to use its leverage with video programmers to limit the 
access of online video distributors (``OVDs'') to important content. 
These OVDs are increasingly offering meaningful competition to cable 
companies like Charter, and the loss of competition caused by the 
proposed merger likely would result in lower-quality services, fewer 
choices, and higher prices for consumers, as well

[[Page 30556]]

as reduced investment and less innovation in this dynamic industry.
    At the same time the Complaint was filed, the United States also 
filed a Stipulation and proposed Final Judgment, which are designed to 
eliminate the anticompetitive effects of the proposed merger. Under the 
proposed Final Judgment, which is explained more fully below, the 
Defendants will be prohibited from using their bargaining leverage with 
video programmers to inhibit the flow of video content to OVDs. The 
proposed Final Judgment will provide a prompt, certain, and effective 
remedy for consumers by preventing New Charter from using its leverage 
over programmers to harm competition. The United States and the 
Defendants have stipulated that the proposed Final Judgment may be 
entered after compliance with the APPA. Entry of the proposed Final 
Judgment would terminate this action, except that the Court would 
retain jurisdiction to construe, modify, or enforce the provisions of 
the proposed Final Judgment, and to punish and remedy violations 
thereof.
    The proposed merger was also subject to review and approval by the 
Federal Communications Commission (``FCC'').\1\ On May 5, 2016, the FCC 
adopted an order approving the transactions subject to certain 
conditions discussed below, and that order was released publicly on May 
10, 2016. The Department and the FCC coordinated closely in their 
reviews of the proposed merger. The FCC's remedy is independent of the 
proposed Final Judgment and not subject to review in this proceeding.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \1\ Under the Communications Act, the FCC has jurisdiction to 
determine whether mergers involving the transfer of a 
telecommunications license are in the ``public interest, 
convenience, and necessity.'' 47 U.S.C. 310(d).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

II. DESCRIPTION OF THE EVENTS GIVING RISE TO THE ALLEGED VIOLATION

A. The Defendants and the Proposed Merger

    Charter is the third-largest cable company in the United States, 
and the sixth-largest multichannel video programming distributor 
(``MVPD'') overall. Charter owns cable systems across 28 states, 
serving approximately 4.8 million residential broadband customers and 
4.2 million residential video customers. Charter reported total 
revenues of around $9.1 billion in 2014, approximately $4.4 billion of 
which were derived from Charter's video business.
    TWC is the second-largest cable company in the United States 
(behind only Comcast Corp.), and the fourth-largest MVPD in the 
country. TWC's cable systems serve approximately 11.7 million 
residential broadband and 10.8 million residential video customers in 
30 states. TWC reported total revenues of approximately $22.8 billion 
in 2014, around $10.4 billion of which were derived from TWC's video 
business.
    BHN is the sixth-largest incumbent cable company in the United 
States and the ninth-largest MVPD overall. It owns cable systems 
serving approximately 2 million video customers across six states, the 
majority of whom are located in the Orlando and Tampa-St. Petersburg, 
Florida areas. BHN is a wholly-owned subsidiary of Advance/Newhouse 
Partnership. Although the Advance/Newhouse Partnership retains the 
authority to manage BHN, it has entered into agreements by which TWC 
performs certain functions for BHN, including the procurement of cable 
programming. In 2014, BHN generated total revenues of around $3.7 
billion, approximately $1.5 billion of which were derived from its 
video business.
    The proposed transactions combining Charter, TWC, and BHN into New 
Charter, as initially agreed to by the Defendants on May 23, 2015, 
would lessen competition substantially in numerous local markets for 
video programming distribution. These transactions are the subject of 
the Complaint and proposed Final Judgment filed by the United States on 
April 25, 2016.

B. The Structure of the Video Programming Distribution Industry

    The video programming distribution industry operates at two 
distinct levels. At the ``upstream'' level, video programmers license 
their content to video programming distributors--both OVDs and 
traditional MVPDs including Charter, TWC, and BHN. At the 
``downstream'' level, the video programming distributors then sell 
subscriptions to various packages of that content and deliver the 
content to residential customers.
[GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TN17MY16.335

1. Video Programmers

    Video programmers produce themselves, or acquire from other 
copyright holders, a collection of professional, full-length programs 
and movies. These video programmers then typically aggregate this 
content into branded networks (e.g., NBC or The History Channel) that 
provide a 24-hour schedule that is attractive to consumers. Large video 
programmers often own multiple individual networks. For instance, The 
Walt Disney Company owns the ABC broadcast network as

[[Page 30557]]

well as many cable networks such as ESPN and The Disney Channel.
    In order to acquire the rights to distribute each network, video 
programming distributors pay the video programmer a license fee, 
generally on a per-subscriber basis. These license fees are an 
important revenue stream for video programmers. Most of the remainder 
of their revenues comes from fees for advertisements placed on their 
networks.
    Video programmers rely on video programming distributors--both 
MVPDs and OVDs--to reach consumers. Unless a video programmer obtains 
carriage in the packages of video programming distributors that reach a 
sufficient number of consumers, the programmers will be unable to earn 
enough revenue in licensing or to attract enough advertising revenue to 
generate a return on their investments in content. For this reason, 
video programmers prefer to have as many video programming distributors 
as possible carry their networks, and particularly seek out the largest 
MVPDs that reach the most customers. If the programmer is unable to 
agree on acceptable terms with a particular distributor, the 
programmer's content will not be available to that distributor's 
customers. This potential consequence gives the largest MVPDs 
significant bargaining leverage in their negotiations with programmers.

2. Multichannel Video Programming Distributors

    Traditional video programming distributors include incumbent cable 
companies such as Charter and TWC; direct broadcast satellite (``DBS'') 
providers such as DirecTV and DISH Network; telephone companies 
(``telcos'') that offer video services such as Verizon and AT&T; and 
overbuilders such as Google Fiber and RCN.\2\ These distributors are 
referred to collectively as MVPDs. MVPDs typically offer hundreds of 
channels of professional video programming to residential customers for 
a monthly subscription fee.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \2\ Overbuilders are providers who have constructed an 
additional wired network to residential consumers for offering video 
and broadband service (i.e., they have ``built over'' the cable and 
phone company networks).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

3. Online Video Programming Distributors

    OVDs are relatively recent entrants into the video programming 
distribution market. They deliver a variety of live and/or on-demand 
video programming over the Internet, whether streamed to Internet-
connected televisions or other devices, or downloaded for later 
viewing. OVDs today include services like Netflix, Hulu, Amazon Prime 
Instant Video, and Sling TV, although, as discussed in more detail 
below, their content selection and business models vary greatly. Unlike 
MVPDs, OVDs do not own distribution facilities and are dependent upon 
broadband Internet access service providers, including incumbent cable 
companies such as Charter and TWC, for the delivery of their content to 
viewers.

C. The Relevant Market and Market Concentration

    The Complaint alleges that video programming distribution 
constitutes a relevant product market and line of commerce under 
Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. The market for video 
programming distribution includes both traditional MVPDs and their 
newer OVD rivals.
    Consumers purchase video programming distribution services from 
among those distributors that can offer such services directly to their 
home. The DBS operators, DirecTV and DISH, can reach almost any 
customer in the continental United States who has an unobstructed line 
of sight to their satellites. OVDs are available to any consumer with 
an Internet service sufficient to deliver video of an acceptable 
quality. In contrast, wireline-based distributors such as cable 
companies and telcos generally must obtain a franchise from local, 
municipal, or state authorities in order to construct and operate a 
wireline network in a specific area, and then build lines to homes in 
that area. A consumer cannot purchase video programming distribution 
services from a wireline distributor operating outside its franchise 
area because the distributor does not have the facilities to reach the 
consumer's home. Thus, although the set of video programming 
distributors able to offer service to individual consumers' residences 
is generally the same within each local community, the set can differ 
from one local community to another.
    According to the Complaint, each local community whose residents 
face the same competitive choices in video programming distribution 
comprises a geographic market and section of the country under Section 
7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. The geographic markets relevant to 
this action are the numerous local markets throughout the United States 
where either Charter, TWC, or BHN is the incumbent cable operator--an 
area encompassing 48 million U.S. television households located across 
41 states. However, because OVDs typically offer services nationwide, 
the Complaint alleges that anticompetitive effects of the proposed 
merger likely extend to the entire United States.
    The incumbent cable companies are often the largest video 
distribution provider in their respective local territories; the 
Defendants' market shares, for example, exceed 50 percent in many local 
markets in which they operate. The DBS providers, DirecTV and DISH 
Network, account for an average of about one third of video programming 
subscribers combined in any given local market. The telcos, including 
AT&T and Verizon, have market shares as high as 40 percent in the 
communities they have entered, but they are only available in limited 
areas and account for about 10 percent of video programming customers 
nationwide. Overbuilders such as Google Fiber can also have moderately 
high shares in particular local markets, but their services are only 
available in a small number of areas and they account for fewer than 
two percent of nationwide video programming distribution subscribers.
    Although OVDs have acquired a significant number of customers over 
the last several years, most of these customers also purchase 
traditional MVPD subscriptions. As a result, OVDs currently have a 
small share of video programming distribution market revenues--likely 
around 5%.

D. Emerging Competition From OVDs in the Relevant Market

1. OVD Business Models and Participants

    OVDs have developed a number of different business models for 
delivering content to consumers. Several OVDs, including Netflix, 
Amazon Prime Instant Video, and Hulu Plus, offer ``subscription video 
on demand'' (``SVOD'') services where consumers typically obtain access 
to a wide library of movies, past-season television shows, and original 
content for a subscription fee.\3\ In addition, some individual cable 
programmers, such as CBS and HBO, have begun offering their content 
directly to consumers on an SVOD basis. For example, HBO's service, 
branded HBO NOW, provides subscribers who pay a monthly fee with access 
to the same HBO content over the Internet that they would receive 
through a subscription to HBO as part of an MVPD package.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \3\ Hulu also offers current-season content from various 
television networks on an ad-supported basis for no subscription 
fee.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    In contrast to these SVOD providers, a few OVDs have recently begun

[[Page 30558]]

offering MVPD-like bundles of live, scheduled content to consumers over 
the Internet. In early 2015, DISH launched Sling TV, a monthly 
subscription service that provides customers access to many of the same 
cable networks that are available through traditional MVPDs. Sony has 
launched a similar service called PlayStation Vue. Unlike SVODs, these 
``virtual'' MVPDs (``vMVPDs'') provide customers the ability to watch 
live sports and news programming, as well as other scheduled 
entertainment programming, at the same time it is available on 
traditional MVPDs.

2. The Effects of OVD Development on Traditional MVPDs

    As OVDs have developed new business models and obtained a wider 
array of attractive video content, they have started to become closer 
substitutes for traditional MVPD services. Although many consumers 
treat OVD services as a complement to traditional MVPD service--for 
example, purchasing services from an SVOD like Netflix to access past 
season content and Netflix's original content but subscribing to an 
MVPD for live and current-season content--some are already using OVDs 
as substitutes for at least a portion of their video consumption. These 
consumers buy smaller content packages from traditional MVPDs, decline 
to take certain premium channels, or purchase fewer VOD offerings, and 
instead substitute content from OVDs, a practice known as ``cord-
shaving.'' In addition, a small, but growing number of MVPD customers 
are ``cutting the cable cord'' completely, using one or more OVDs as a 
replacement for their MVPD service. Finally, some younger consumers are 
emerging as ``cord nevers'' who do not seek out an MVPD subscription in 
the first place.
    Absent interference from the established MVPDs, OVDs are likely to 
continue to grow, and to become stronger competitors to MVPDs. 
Moreover, to the extent that OVDs continue to develop services that 
more closely resemble those offered by traditional MVPDs, such as the 
live programming offered by vMVPDs or the current season content 
offered by certain SVODs, traditional MVPDs will likely face greater 
substitution to OVD services. To this end, the Defendants' internal 
documents show that they have typically been comparatively less 
concerned about competition from certain SVOD providers, like Netflix, 
that do not offer live or current-season programming, and more 
concerned by the threat posed by vMVPDs like Sling TV and SVODs like 
HBO NOW that offer current season content.

3. Traditional MVPDs' Responses to the Growth of OVDs

    The Defendants and many other MVPDs recognize the threat that the 
growth of OVDs pose to their video distribution businesses. Numerous 
internal documents reflect the Defendants' assessment that OVDs are 
growing quickly and pose a competitive threat to traditional forms of 
video programming distribution. MVPDs have responded to this growth in 
various ways. To keep their customers from migrating some or all of 
their viewing to OVDs, many MVPDs, including the Defendants, have 
introduced new and less expensive packages with smaller numbers of 
channels, increased the amount of content available on an on-demand 
basis, and made content available to subscribers on devices other than 
traditional cable set-top boxes. At the same time, however, some MVPDs 
have sought to restrain nascent OVD competition directly by exercising 
their leverage over video programmers to restrict video programmers' 
ability to license content to OVDs. As alleged in the Complaint, and 
explained in more detail below, TWC has been an industry leader in 
seeking such restrictions, and the formation of New Charter will create 
an entity with an increased ability and incentive to do so.

E. The Anticompetitive Effects of the Proposed Merger

    Although Defendants do not compete to provide video distribution 
services to consumers in the same local geographic markets, the Clayton 
Act is also concerned with mergers that threaten to reduce the number 
or quality of choices available to consumers by increasing the merging 
parties' incentive or ability to engage in conduct that would foreclose 
competition.\4\ For example, a merger may create, or substantially 
enhance, the ability or incentive of the merged firm to protect its 
market power by denying or raising the price of an input to the firm's 
rivals.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \4\ See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 317 
(1962) (noting that the Clayton Act intended to make illegal ``not 
only [] mergers between actual competitors, but also [] vertical and 
conglomerate mergers whose effect may tend to lessen competition in 
any line of commerce in any section of the country.''); FTC v. 
Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.S. 568, 577 (1967) (``All mergers are 
within the reach of Sec.  7, and all must be tested by the same 
standard, whether they are classified as horizontal, vertical, 
conglomerate.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    As alleged in the Complaint, New Charter will be significantly 
larger than each of the Defendants individually, and thus will have a 
greater incentive and ability to use its bargaining power with video 
programmers to protect its market power in the local markets for video 
programming distribution. Specifically, following the merger, New 
Charter will be the one of the largest MVPDs in the country, with over 
17 million subscribers in 41 states, and will therefore be a critical 
distribution channel for video programmers. The Complaint alleges that 
this greater scale will give New Charter more leverage to demand that 
programmers agree to limit their distribution to OVDs, enabling the 
merged firm to increase barriers to entry for OVDs or otherwise make 
OVDs less competitive.
    The Complaint also alleges that New Charter will have increased 
incentive to engage in such behavior because it will stand to lose 
substantially more profits than Charter, TWC, and BHN individually if 
OVDs take business from traditional MVPDs, and it will internalize more 
of the benefits of harming OVDs. The Defendants' specific means for 
foreclosing OVDs--ADM clauses and other restrictive contracting 
provisions--are discussed in more detail below.

1. TWC Is the Industry Leader in Imposing ADMs and Other Restrictive 
Programming Clauses that Limit Video Programmers' Rights to License to 
OVDs

    Video programmers sign lengthy licensing agreements with 
distributors that establish the terms on which the distributors will 
carry the programmers' networks. Sometimes, these licensing agreements 
include restrictions on the other distributors to whom the programmer 
may license content, or on other ways the programmer may make the 
content available to consumers. One type of restriction is often 
referred to in the industry as an ``alternative distribution means'' 
(``ADM'') clause. ADM clauses take many forms, and in some cases can 
have significant consequences for programmers' ability to license to 
OVDs. For example, some ADMs prohibit a video programmer from licensing 
content to OVDs for an extended period of time after the content is 
first aired on traditional MVPDs--permanently blocking OVDs from being 
able to offer current-season content from those programmers. Other ADMs 
prohibit the programmer from licensing content to OVDs unless the OVDs 
meet a number of strict (and sometimes elaborate) criteria that can be 
difficult to satisfy.\5\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \5\ For instance, an ADM in one MVPD's contract with a video 
programmer prohibited the programmer from licensing to any OVD 
unless that OVD offered a package that included thirty-five 
channels, including at least two channels each from three out of a 
list of six large video programmers.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 30559]]

    TWC has been the most aggressive MVPD at seeking and obtaining 
restrictive ADM clauses in recent years. The Department's review of 
hundreds of programming contracts and ordinary course business 
documents revealed that TWC has obtained numerous ADMs that limit 
distribution to paid OVDs. Other distributors, by contrast, have 
rarely, if ever, sought or obtained such clauses, or have only obtained 
ADMs that are much less restrictive. TWC's success in seeking and 
obtaining ADMs is likely attributable in part to its bargaining 
leverage over video programmers; although such programmers might 
disfavor such restrictions because they require the programmer to 
forsake opportunities to earn revenues from OVDs, they are more likely 
to agree to a large MVPD such as TWC's demand to include them because 
they do not want to lose access to TWC's millions of cable subscribers.
    The Department's investigation further suggested that TWC may be 
the most aggressive at obtaining such clauses because, other than 
Comcast, TWC has more to lose from the expansion of OVDs than any other 
traditional MVPD. Although Comcast also has substantial video profits 
at risk, it is prohibited from entering into or enforcing any 
provisions that restrict distribution to OVDs under the terms of a 
consent decree entered in United States v. Comcast Corp.\6\ By 
contrast, distributors with fewer subscribers than TWC have less to 
lose from the expansion of OVDs, and, in some cases, may actually 
support OVD expansion because they make little or no profit margin on 
their video distribution businesses and would prefer to improve the 
attractiveness of their broadband Internet access services. Meanwhile, 
the two DBS providers, DISH and DirecTV, have historically been 
comparable to TWC in size, but because of their different distribution 
technology and their customer demographics, may perceive a lower threat 
from OVDs. In fact, DISH is offering an OVD service of its own--Sling 
TV--and DirecTV recently announced plans to offer a similar OVD 
service.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \6\ See Final Judgment, United States et al. v. Comcast et al., 
Civil Action No. 1:11cv-00106, 2011-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ]77,585, 2011 
WL 5402137 (D.D.C. Sept. 1, 2011), available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/case-document/file/492196/download.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

2. The Proposed Transaction Increases New Charter's Ability and 
Incentive To Obtain ADMs and Other Restrictive Programming Clauses

    The number and scope of the ADMs that TWC obtained prior to the 
merger suggests that TWC believes that these ADM clauses are worth 
whatever consideration it must provide video programmers in return. 
After the merger, New Charter, with over 17 million video subscribers 
in 41 states, will have even more leverage than TWC to demand that 
programmers agree to ADMs. Given the importance of New Charter as a 
distribution channel, programmers will be less likely to risk losing 
access to New Charter's considerable subscriber base--which is almost 
60 percent larger than TWC alone--and will be more likely to accept to 
New Charter's demands. Moreover, since New Charter will have far more 
profits at risk from increased OVD competition than Charter, TWC, or 
BHN standing alone, it will be willing to provide greater consideration 
to programmers to obtain such clauses. As a result, New Charter can be 
expected to seek and obtain ADMs with more programmers than TWC has to 
date, and the ADMs are likely to be more restrictive than TWC's current 
ADM provisions. As alleged in the Complaint, such ADMs could negatively 
affect OVDs' business models and undermine their ability to provide 
robust video offerings that compete with the offerings of traditional 
MVPDs. The weakening of OVD competition will result in lower-quality 
services, fewer consumer choices, and higher prices.

4. Entry Is Unlikely To Reverse the Anticompetitive Effects of the 
Proposed Merger

    Successful entry into the traditional video programming 
distribution business is difficult and requires an enormous upfront 
investment to create a distribution infrastructure. As alleged in the 
Complaint, additional entry into wireline or DBS distribution is not 
likely to be significant for the next several years. Telcos have been 
willing to incur some of the enormous costs to modify their existing 
telephone infrastructure to distribute video, and will continue to do 
so, but only in certain areas. Other new providers, such as Google 
Fiber, are also expanding services, but the time and expense required 
to build to each new area makes expansion slow. Therefore, traditional 
MVPDs' market shares are likely to be fairly stable over the next 
several years.
    OVDs represent the most likely prospect for successful and 
significant competitive entry into the existing video programming 
distribution market. However, in addition to the other barriers they 
face, OVDs must obtain access to a sufficient amount of content to 
become viable distribution businesses, and the proposed merger will 
likely increase that barrier to entry even further.

III. EXPLANATION OF THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT

    The proposed Final Judgment ensures that New Charter will not 
impede competition by using programming contracts to prevent the flow 
of content to OVDs. The proposed Final Judgment thereby protects 
consumers by eliminating the likely anticompetitive effects of the 
proposed merger alleged in the Complaint.

A. The Proposed Final Judgment Prohibits Defendants From Limiting 
Distribution to OVDs Through Restrictive Licensing Practices

    As discussed above, certain types of contract provisions, such as 
ADMs, can have the purpose and effect of limiting distribution to OVDs. 
However, not all provisions that limit distribution are 
anticompetitive. Reflecting this reality, Sections IV.A and IV.B of the 
proposed Final Judgment set forth broad prohibitions on restrictive 
contracting practices, while Section IV.C delineates a narrowly 
tailored set of exceptions. Taken together, these provisions ensure 
that New Charter cannot use restrictive contract terms to harm the 
development of OVDs, but preserve programmers' incentives to produce 
quality programming and New Charter's ability to compete with other 
distributors to obtain marquee content.
    Section IV.A of the proposed Final Judgment prohibits New Charter 
from entering into or enforcing agreements that forbid, limit, or 
create incentives to limit the provision of video programming to OVDs. 
This language prevents New Charter from enforcing the ADM provisions in 
current TWC contracts, or from entering into new provisions.
    Section IV.B provides additional detail as to the types of terms 
that could create ``incentives to limit'' distribution to OVDs. The 
Department's investigation revealed that TWC has obtained ADM 
provisions for the purpose of attempting to limit distribution to OVDs. 
However, once those agreements are prohibited, New Charter could 
substitute ADMs with more subtle types of contract provisions that do 
not directly limit distribution to

[[Page 30560]]

OVDs, but make it financially unattractive for video programmers to 
license content to OVDs. For instance, absent relief, New Charter could 
enter into an agreement that permits a video programmer to license 
content to an OVD, but specifies that so licensing will entitle New 
Charter to a massive license fee discount. To prevent evasion of the 
ban on ADMs, Section IV.B.1 clarifies that such ``penalty'' provisions 
that create incentives to limit distribution to OVDs are not permitted.
    Alternatively, New Charter could enter into certain kinds of ``most 
favored nation'' (``MFN'') provisions that are designed to create 
incentives to limit distribution to OVDs. Although MFN provisions are 
ubiquitous in the industry--for example, many MVPDs use MFN provisions 
entitling the MVPD to the lowest license fee that the programmer offers 
to any other MVPD--the Department's investigation revealed that some 
MVPDs were utilizing certain provisions that, while referred to as 
``MFNs,'' actually require much more than equal treatment. 
Specifically, some provisions, commonly referred to as ``unconditional 
MFNs'' or ``cherry-picking MFNs,'' require that a programmer provide an 
MVPD the most favorable term the programmer has offered to any other 
distributor, even if that other distributor agreed to additional 
payment or other conditions in exchange for receiving that term.\7\ As 
a result of an unconditional MFN, the programmer may be reluctant to 
license the additional content to the other distributor in the first 
place.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \7\ For example, a programmer may enter into an agreement with 
Distributor A that provides Distributor A with extra content (for 
instance, additional video-on-demand rights) in exchange for an 
extra payment. If the programmer has an unconditional MFN with 
Distributor B, the programmer may then be required to provide the 
additional video-on-demand rights to Distributor B without 
Distributor B having to make the extra payment. By contrast, a more 
typical--and less problematic--MFN would entitle Distributor B to 
the additional content only if Distributor B agreed to pay the same 
additional fee paid by Distributor A.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    Although unconditional MFNs are uncommon today, and the Defendants 
have only a few such provisions in their current contracts, the 
Department was concerned that New Charter could replace ADMs with 
unconditional MFNs in an effort to circumvent the proposed Final 
Judgment. For example, New Charter might obtain an unconditional MFN 
from a programmer that would entitle New Charter to receive at no 
additional cost any content a programmer makes available to an OVD, 
regardless of payments or other conditions with which the OVD must 
comply. In such case, by providing programming to an OVD, the 
programmer might face significant economic disadvantages in the form of 
losing the opportunity to monetize the content through distribution by 
New Charter. As a result, unconditional MFNs could create significant 
disincentives for programmers to license content to OVDs. For these 
reasons, Section IV.B.2 of the proposed Final Judgment prohibits New 
Charter from entering into or enforcing unconditional MFNs against 
programmers for distributing their content to OVDs.\8\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \8\ Specifically, Section IV.B.2.i provides that New Charter may 
not require a programmer to provide New Charter the same terms 
offered to an OVD unless New Charter also accepts any conditions 
that are integrally related, logically linked, or directly tied to 
those terms. The language chosen for this provision mirrors language 
that is common in conditional MFN provisions throughout the 
industry. Also consistent with other conditional MFNs in the 
industry, Section IV.B.2.ii states that Charter need not comply with 
related terms and conditions if it is unable to do so for 
technological or regulatory reasons.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    Section IV.C of the proposed Final Judgment establishes three 
narrow exceptions to the broad prohibitions in Sections IV.A and IV.B. 
First, New Charter may prohibit the programmer from making content 
available on the Internet for free for 30 days after its initial 
airing, if New Charter has paid a fee for the video programming. The 
Department's investigation revealed that such limitations on free 
distribution are ubiquitous in the industry, and the Department has 
discovered no evidence that such provisions are harmful to competition.
    Second, New Charter may enter into an agreement in which the 
programmer provides content exclusively to New Charter, and to no other 
MVPD or OVD. Although uncommon, a few programmers wish to make some of 
their content available to only one distributor. This relationship then 
incentivizes the distributor to vigorously market the content, and thus 
can be procompetitive in some circumstances. The proposed Final 
Judgment ensures that New Charter can continue to compete with other 
distributors to obtain these kinds of exclusives. As long as the 
exclusivity applies to all other video programming distributors, and 
does not narrowly prohibit distribution only to OVDs, the Department 
has no basis to believe such provisions will always or usually be 
harmful.\9\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \9\ The Department retains the authority to challenge under 
Sections 1 or 2 of the Sherman Act any exclusive agreement in the 
future that the evidence demonstrates unreasonably restrains trade 
or creates or enhances monopoly power. See Proposed Final Judgment 
at Sec.  VII (No Limitation of Government Rights).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    Third, New Charter may condition carriage of programming on its 
cable system on terms which require it to receive as favorable material 
terms as other MVPDs or OVDs, except to the extent such terms would be 
inconsistent with the purpose of the proposed Final Judgment. That is, 
New Charter may enter into the kinds of ordinary conditional MFNs that 
are ubiquitous in the industry, such as a provision which entitles New 
Charter to the lowest license fee paid by any other distributor. This 
provision explicitly does not override Section IV.B.2's ban on the 
application of unconditional MFNs to OVD distribution. Importantly, New 
Charter may not use MFNs as a back door to obtain provisions which are 
otherwise ``inconsistent with the purpose of Sections A and B.'' For 
instance, even if another distributor obtains a provision which 
``create[s] incentives to limit'' a programmer's provision of 
programming to an OVD, New Charter cannot use an MFN to add that other 
distributor's provision to New Charter's own contract.

2. The Proposed Final Judgment Prohibits Defendants From Discriminating 
Against, Retaliating Against, or Punishing Video Programmers

    Section IV.D of the proposed Final Judgment prohibits Defendants 
from discriminating against, retaliating against, or punishing any 
Video Programmer for providing programming to any OVD. This provision 
ensures that even though Defendants are no longer permitted to 
contractually prohibit or deter video programmers from licensing 
content to OVDs, the Defendants are not able to instead deter such 
licensing through threats or punishment. Section IV.D also prohibits 
Defendants from discriminating against, retaliating against, or 
punishing any video programmer for invoking any provisions of the 
proposed Final Judgment or any FCC rule or order, or for furnishing 
information to the Department concerning Defendants' compliance with 
the proposed Final Judgment.
    Negotiations between video programmers and MVPDs are often 
contentious, high-stakes affairs, and it is common for one or both 
sides to the negotiation to threaten to walk away, or even to 
temporarily terminate the relationship (sometimes called a ``blackout'' 
or ``going dark'') in order to secure a better deal. The proposed Final 
Judgment is not concerned with such negotiating tactics and therefore 
clarifies that ``[p]ursuing a more advantageous deal with a Video 
Programmer does not constitute discrimination, retaliation, or

[[Page 30561]]

punishment.'' Rather, Section IV.D is designed to prevent situations 
where New Charter intentionally decides to forgo an agreement with a 
programmer that would otherwise be economical for New Charter in order 
to obtain the long-term benefits of deterring video programmers from 
licensing content to OVDs or cooperating with the Department or the 
FCC.

3. Provision of Defendants' FCC Interconnection Reports

    Although the Department's Complaint focuses on the likely 
competitive harm resulting from New Charter's imposition of ADMs and 
other contractual restrictions on video programmers, the Department 
also investigated the potential for the proposed merger to increase the 
price New Charter will charge Internet content companies, including 
OVDs, for access to its broadband subscribers. OVDs rely on broadband 
connections provided by other companies to reach their customers, and 
the Defendants are also major providers of Internet access service. 
Therefore, the Department examined whether the merger could increase 
both the incentive and ability of New Charter to use its control over 
the interconnection to New Charter's broadband Internet service 
provider network to try and disadvantage online video competitors.
    The FCC's order approving the merger imposes an obligation on New 
Charter to make interconnection available on a non-discriminatory, 
settlement-free basis to any Internet content provider, transit 
provider, or content delivery network (``CDN'') who meets certain basic 
criteria. Although this policy only directly protects those sending 
large volumes of traffic, even smaller sources who do not qualify for 
direct interconnection ought to find ample bandwidth available at 
competitive prices because large transit and CDN providers will be 
guaranteed access, and could resell that capacity. Thus, the Department 
expects that the FCC's order will prevent any merger-related harm to 
Internet content companies, including OVDs. In light of the FCC's 
remedy, the Department did not target interconnection in its Complaint 
and elected not to pursue duplicative relief with respect to 
interconnection in the proposed Final Judgment. However, in order to 
assist the Department in monitoring future developments with regard to 
interconnection and in taking whatever action might be appropriate to 
prevent anticompetitive conduct, Section IV.E requires New Charter to 
provide the Department with copies of the regular reports that New 
Charter furnishes to the FCC pursuant to the FCC's order.

D. Term of the Proposed Final Judgment

    Section VIII of the proposed Final Judgment provides that the Final 
Judgment will expire seven years from the date of entry. The Department 
believes this time period is long enough to ensure that New Charter 
cannot harm OVD competitors at a crucial point in their development 
while accounting for the rapidly evolving nature of the video 
distribution market. After five years, Section VIII permits Charter to 
request that the Department reevaluate whether the Final Judgment 
remains necessary to protect competition. If at such time the 
Department concludes that the market has evolved such that the 
protections of the decree are no longer necessary, it will recommend to 
the Court that the Final Judgment be terminated.

IV. REMEDIES AVAILABLE TO POTENTIAL PRIVATE LITIGANTS

    Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 15, provides that any 
person who has been injured as a result of conduct prohibited by the 
antitrust laws may bring suit in federal court to recover three times 
the damages the person has suffered, as well as costs and reasonable 
attorneys' fees. Entry of the proposed Final Judgment will neither 
impair nor assist the bringing of any private antitrust damage action. 
Under the provisions of Section 5(a) of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 
16(a), the proposed Final Judgment has no prima facie effect in any 
subsequent private lawsuit that may be brought against Defendants.

V. PROCEDURES AVAILABLE FOR MODIFICATION OF THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT

    The United States and Defendants have stipulated that the proposed 
Final Judgment may be entered by the Court after compliance with the 
provisions of the APPA, provided that the United States has not 
withdrawn its consent. The APPA conditions entry upon the Court's 
determination that the proposed Final Judgment is in the public 
interest.
    The APPA provides a period of at least 60 days preceding the 
effective date of the proposed Final Judgment within which any person 
may submit to the United States written comments regarding the proposed 
Final Judgment. Any person who wishes to comment should do so within 60 
days of the date of publication of this Competitive Impact Statement in 
the Federal Register, or the last date of publication in a newspaper of 
the summary of this Competitive Impact Statement, whichever is later. 
All comments received during this period will be considered by the 
United States, which remains free to withdraw its consent to the 
proposed Final Judgment at any time prior to the Court's entry of 
judgment. The comments and the response of the United States will be 
filed with the Court. In addition, comments will be posted on the U.S. 
Department of Justice, Antitrust Division's internet Web site and, 
under certain circumstances, published in the Federal Register. Written 
comments should be submitted to:

Scott A. Scheele
Chief, Telecommunications and Media Enforcement Section
Antitrust Division
United States Department of Justice
450 Fifth Street NW., Suite 7000
Washington, DC 20530

    The proposed Final Judgment provides that the Court retains 
jurisdiction over this action, and the parties may apply to the Court 
for any order necessary or appropriate for the modification, 
interpretation, or enforcement of the Final Judgment.

VI. ALTERNATIVES TO THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT

    The United States considered, as an alternative to the proposed 
Final Judgment, seeking preliminary and permanent injunctions against 
Defendants' transactions and proceeding to a full trial on the merits. 
The United States is satisfied, however, that the relief in the 
proposed Final Judgment will preserve competition for the provision of 
video programming distribution services in the United States. Thus, the 
proposed Final Judgment would protect competition as effectively as 
would any remedy available through litigation, but avoids the time, 
expense, and uncertainty of a full trial on the merits.

VII. STANDARD OF REVIEW UNDER THE APPA FOR THE PROPOSED FINAL JUDGMENT

    The Clayton Act, as amended by the APPA, requires that proposed 
consent judgments in antitrust cases brought by the United States be 
subject to a sixty-day comment period, after which the court shall 
determine whether entry of the proposed Final Judgment ``is in the 
public interest.'' 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1). In making that determination, 
the court, in accordance with the statute as amended in 2004, is 
required to consider:

    (A) the competitive impact of such judgment, including 
termination of alleged violations, provisions for enforcement and 
modification, duration of relief sought,

[[Page 30562]]

anticipated effects of alternative remedies actually considered, 
whether its terms are ambiguous, and any other competitive 
considerations bearing upon the adequacy of such judgment that the 
court deems necessary to a determination of whether the consent 
judgment is in the public interest; and
    (B) the impact of entry of such judgment upon competition in the 
relevant market or markets, upon the public generally and 
individuals alleging specific injury from the violations set forth 
in the complaint including consideration of the public benefit, if 
any, to be derived from a determination of the issues at trial.

15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1)(A) & (B). In considering these statutory factors, 
the Court's inquiry is necessarily a limited one as the government is 
entitled to ``broad discretion to settle with the defendant within the 
reaches of the public interest.'' United States v. Microsoft Corp., 56 
F.3d 1448, 1461 (D.C. Cir. 1995); see generally United States v. SBC 
Commc'ns, Inc., 489 F. Supp. 2d 1 (D.D.C. 2007) (assessing public 
interest standard under the Tunney Act); United States v, U.S. Airways 
Group, Inc., 38 F. Supp. 3d 69, 75 (D.D.C. 2014) (explaining that the 
``court's inquiry is limited'' in Tunney Act settlements); United 
States v. InBev N.V./S.A., No. 08-1965 (JR), 2009-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ] 
76,736, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *3, (D.D.C. Aug. 11, 2009) 
(noting that the court's review of a consent judgment is limited and 
only inquires ``into whether the government's determination that the 
proposed remedies will cure the antitrust violations alleged in the 
complaint was reasonable, and whether the mechanism to enforce the 
final judgment are clear and manageable.'').\10\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \10\ The 2004 amendments substituted ``shall'' for ``may'' in 
directing relevant factors for courts to consider and amended the 
list of factors to focus on competitive considerations and to 
address potentially ambiguous judgment terms. Compare 15 U.S.C. 
16(e) (2004), with 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1) (2006); see also SBC Commc'ns, 
489 F. Supp. 2d at 11 (concluding that the 2004 amendments 
``effected minimal changes'' to Tunney Act review).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    As the United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia 
Circuit has held, under the APPA a court considers, among other things, 
the relationship between the remedy secured and the specific 
allegations set forth in the government's complaint, whether the decree 
is sufficiently clear, whether enforcement mechanisms are sufficient, 
and whether the decree may positively harm third parties. See 
Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1458-62. With respect to the adequacy of the 
relief secured by the decree, a court may not ``engage in an 
unrestricted evaluation of what relief would best serve the public.'' 
United States v. BNS, Inc., 858 F.2d 456, 462 (9th Cir. 1988) (quoting 
United States v. Bechtel Corp., 648 F.2d 660, 666 (9th Cir. 1981)); see 
also Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1460-62; United States v. Alcoa, Inc., 152 
F. Supp. 2d 37, 40 (D.D.C. 2001); InBev, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, 
at *3. Courts have held that:

[t]he balancing of competing social and political interests affected 
by a proposed antitrust consent decree must be left, in the first 
instance, to the discretion of the Attorney General. The court's 
role in protecting the public interest is one of insuring that the 
government has not breached its duty to the public in consenting to 
the decree. The court is required to determine not whether a 
particular decree is the one that will best serve society, but 
whether the settlement is ``within the reaches of the public 
interest.'' More elaborate requirements might undermine the 
effectiveness of antitrust enforcement by consent decree.

Bechtel, 648 F.2d at 666 (emphasis added) (citations omitted).\11\ In 
determining whether a proposed settlement is in the public interest, a 
district court ``must accord deference to the government's predictions 
about the efficacy of its remedies, and may not require that the 
remedies perfectly match the alleged violations.'' SBC Commc'ns, 489 F. 
Supp. 2d at 17; see also U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 75 (noting 
that a court should not reject the proposed remedies because it 
believes others are preferable); Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461 (noting the 
need for courts to be ``deferential to the government's predictions as 
to the effect of the proposed remedies''); United States v. Archer-
Daniels-Midland Co., 272 F. Supp. 2d 1, 6 (D.D.C. 2003) (noting that 
the court should grant due respect to the United States' prediction as 
to the effect of proposed remedies, its perception of the market 
structure, and its views of the nature of the case).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \11\ Cf. BNS, 858 F.2d at 464 (holding that the court's 
``ultimate authority under the [APPA] is limited to approving or 
disapproving the consent decree''); United States v. Gillette Co., 
406 F. Supp. 713, 716 (D. Mass. 1975) (noting that, in this way, the 
court is constrained to ``look at the overall picture not 
hypercritically, nor with a microscope, but with an artist's 
reducing glass''). See generally Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461 
(discussing whether ``the remedies [obtained in the decree are] so 
inconsonant with the allegations charged as to fall outside of the 
`reaches of the public interest''').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    Courts have greater flexibility in approving proposed consent 
decrees than in crafting their own decrees following a finding of 
liability in a litigated matter. ``[A] proposed decree must be approved 
even if it falls short of the remedy the court would impose on its own, 
as long as it falls within the range of acceptability or is `within the 
reaches of public interest.''' United States v. Am. Tel. & Tel. Co., 
552 F. Supp. 131, 151 (D.D.C. 1982) (citations omitted) (quoting United 
States v. Gillette Co., 406 F. Supp. 713, 716 (D. Mass. 1975)), aff'd 
sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983); see also U.S. 
Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 76 (noting that room must be made for the 
government to grant concessions in the negotiation process for 
settlements (citing Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1461); United States v. Alcan 
Aluminum Ltd., 605 F. Supp. 619, 622 (W.D. Ky. 1985) (approving the 
consent decree even though the court would have imposed a greater 
remedy). To meet this standard, the United States ``need only provide a 
factual basis for concluding that the settlements are reasonably 
adequate remedies for the alleged harms.'' SBC Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp. 
2d at 17.
    Moreover, the court's role under the APPA is limited to reviewing 
the remedy in relationship to the violations that the United States has 
alleged in its Complaint, and does not authorize the court to 
``construct [its] own hypothetical case and then evaluate the decree 
against that case.'' Microsoft, 56 F.3d at 1459; see also U.S. Airways, 
38 F. Supp. 3d at 75 (noting that the court must simply determine 
whether there is a factual foundation for the government's decisions 
such that its conclusions regarding the proposed settlements are 
reasonable); InBev, 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 84787, at *20 (``the `public 
interest' is not to be measured by comparing the violations alleged in 
the complaint against those the court believes could have, or even 
should have, been alleged''). Because the ``court's authority to review 
the decree depends entirely on the government's exercising its 
prosecutorial discretion by bringing a case in the first place,'' it 
follows that ``the court is only authorized to review the decree 
itself,'' and not to ``effectively redraft the complaint'' to inquire 
into other matters that the United States did not pursue. Microsoft, 56 
F.3d at 1459-60. As this Court confirmed in SBC Communications, courts 
``cannot look beyond the complaint in making the public interest 
determination unless the complaint is drafted so narrowly as to make a 
mockery of judicial power.'' SBC Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 15.
    In its 2004 amendments, Congress made clear its intent to preserve 
the practical benefits of utilizing consent decrees in antitrust 
enforcement, adding the unambiguous instruction that ``[n]othing in 
this section shall be construed to require the court to conduct an 
evidentiary hearing or to require the court to permit anyone to 
intervene.'' 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(2); see also U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d 
at 76

[[Page 30563]]

(indicating that a court is not required to hold an evidentiary hearing 
or to permit intervenors as part of its review under the Tunney Act). 
The language wrote into the statute what Congress intended when it 
enacted the Tunney Act in 1974, as Senator Tunney explained: ``[t]he 
court is nowhere compelled to go to trial or to engage in extended 
proceedings which might have the effect of vitiating the benefits of 
prompt and less costly settlement through the consent decree process.'' 
119 Cong. Rec. 24,598 (1973) (statement of Sen. Tunney). Rather, the 
procedure for the public interest determination is left to the 
discretion of the court, with the recognition that the court's ``scope 
of review remains sharply proscribed by precedent and the nature of 
Tunney Act proceedings.'' SBC Commc'ns, 489 F. Supp. 2d at 11.\12\ A 
court can make its public interest determination based on the 
competitive impact statement and response to public comments alone. 
U.S. Airways, 38 F. Supp. 3d at 76.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \12\ See United States v. Enova Corp., 107 F. Supp. 2d 10, 17 
(D.D.C. 2000) (noting that the ``Tunney Act expressly allows the 
court to make its public interest determination on the basis of the 
competitive impact statement and response to comments alone''); 
United States v. Mid-Am. Dairymen, Inc., No. 73-CV-681-W-1, 1977-1 
Trade Cas. (CCH) ] 61,508, at 71,980, *22 (W.D.
    Mo. 1977) (``Absent a showing of corrupt failure of the 
government to discharge its duty, the Court, in making its public 
interest finding, should . . . carefully consider the explanations 
of the government in the competitive impact statement and its 
responses to comments in order to determine whether those 
explanations are reasonable under the circumstances.''); S. Rep. No. 
93-298, at 6 (1973) (``Where the public interest can be meaningfully 
evaluated simply on the basis of briefs and oral arguments, that is 
the approach that should be utilized.'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

VIII. DETERMINATIVE DOCUMENTS

    Appendix B to the FCC's Memorandum Opinion and Order, In re 
Applications of Charter Communications, Inc., Time Warner Cable Inc., 
and Advance/Newhouse Partnership for Consent to the Transfer of Control 
of Licenses and Authorizations, FCC MB Docket No. 15-149 (adopted May 
5, 2016; released May 10, 2016), was the only determinative document or 
material within the meaning of the APPA considered by the Department in 
formulating the proposed Final Judgment. This document is available on 
the FCC's Web site at https://apps.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/FCC-16-59A1.pdf, and will also be made available on the Antitrust 
Division's Web site at https://www.justice.gov/atr/case/us-v-charter-communications-inc-et-al.

Dated: May 10, 2016

Respectfully submitted,

/s/--------------------------------------------------------------------

Robert A. Lepore,

Telecommunications & Media, Enforcement Section, Antitrust Division, 
U.S. Department of Justice, 450 Fifth Street NW., Suite 7000, 
Washington, DC 20530, Telephone: (202) 532-4928, Facsimile: (202) 
514-6381, Email: [email protected]

United States District Court for the District of Columbia

    United States of America, Plaintiff, v. Charter Communications, 
Inc., Time Warner Cable Inc, Advance/Newhouse Partnership, and 
Bright House Networks, LLC, Defendants.

Case No.: 1:16-cv-00759
Judge: Royce C. Lamberth
Filed: 04/25/2016

[PROPOSED] FINAL JUDGMENT

    WHEREAS, Plaintiff, the United States of America, filed its 
Complaint on April 25, 2016 alleging that Defendants propose to enter 
into transactions the likely effect of which would be to lessen 
competition substantially in the market for the timely distribution of 
professional, full-length video programming to residential customers 
(``video programming distribution'') across the United States in 
violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18, and Plaintiff 
and Defendants, by their respective attorneys, have consented to the 
entry of this Final Judgment without trial or adjudication of any issue 
of fact or law, and without this Final Judgment constituting any 
evidence against or admission by any party regarding any issue of fact 
or law;
    AND WHEREAS, Defendants agree to be bound by the provisions of this 
Final Judgment pending its approval by the Court;
    AND WHEREAS, Plaintiff requires Defendants to agree to undertake 
certain actions and refrain from certain conduct for the purpose of 
remedying the loss of competition alleged in the Complaint;
    AND WHEREAS, Defendants have represented to the United States that 
the actions and conduct restrictions can and will be undertaken and 
that Defendants will later raise no claim of hardship or difficulty as 
grounds for asking the Court to modify any of the provisions contained 
below;
    NOW THEREFORE, before any testimony is taken, without trial or 
adjudication of any issue of fact or law, and upon consent of the 
parties, it is ORDERED, ADJUDGED, AND DECREED:

I. JURISDICTION

    This Court has jurisdiction over the subject matter of and each of 
the parties to this action. The Complaint states a claim upon which 
relief may be granted against Defendants under Section 7 of the Clayton 
Act, as amended, 15 U.S.C. 18.

II. DEFINITIONS

    As used in this Final Judgment:
    A. ``Advance/Newhouse'' means defendant Advance/Newhouse 
Partnership, a New York partnership with headquarters in East Syracuse, 
New York, its successors and assigns, and its Subsidiaries, divisions, 
groups, affiliates, partnerships and joint ventures, and their 
directors, officers, managers, agents, and employees, in their capacity 
as directors, officers, managers, agents, and employees of the 
foregoing.
    B. ``Bright House'' means defendant Bright House Networks, LLC, a 
Delaware limited liability company with headquarters in East Syracuse, 
New York, its successors and assigns, and its Subsidiaries, divisions, 
groups, affiliates, partnerships and joint ventures, and their 
directors, officers, managers, agents, and employees, in their capacity 
as directors, officers, managers, agents, and employees of the 
foregoing.
    C. ``Charter'' means defendant Charter Communications, Inc., a 
Delaware corporation with headquarters in Stamford, Connecticut, its 
successors and assigns (including, without limitation, CCH I, LLC), and 
its Subsidiaries, divisions, groups, affiliates, partnerships and joint 
ventures, and their directors, officers, managers, agents, and 
employees, in their capacity as directors, officers, managers, agents, 
and employees of the foregoing.
    D. ``Defendants'' means Charter, TWC, Bright House, and Advance/
Newhouse, acting individually or collectively. Notwithstanding the 
foregoing, Advance/Newhouse is not a ``Defendant'' for purposes of 
Section IV.
    E. ``Department of Justice'' means the United States Department of 
Justice Antitrust Division.
    F. ``MVPD'' means a multichannel video programming distributor as 
that term is defined on the date of entry of this Final Judgment in 47 
CFR 76.1200(b), in its capacity as an MVPD.
    G. ``OVD'' means any service that (1) distributes Video Programming 
in the United States by means of the Internet; (2) is not a component 
of an MVPD subscription; and (3) is not solely available to customers 
of an Internet access service owned or operated by the Person providing 
the service or an affiliate of the Person providing the service. For 
avoidance of doubt, this definition (1) includes a service offered by a 
Video Programmer for the distribution of its own Video

[[Page 30564]]

Programming by means of the Internet to Persons other than subscribers 
of an MVPD service; (2) includes a service offered by an MVPD that 
offers Video Programming by means of the Internet outside its MVPD 
service territory as a service separate and independent of an MVPD 
subscription; and (3) excludes an MVPD that offers Video Programming by 
means of the Internet to homes inside its MVPD service territory as a 
component of an MVPD subscription.
    H. ``Person'' means any natural person, corporation, company, 
partnership, joint venture, firm, association, proprietorship, agency, 
board, authority, commission, office, or other business or legal 
entity, whether private or governmental.
    I. ``Subsidiary'' refers to any Person in which there is partial 
(25 percent or more) or total ownership or control between the 
specified Person and any other Person. Notwithstanding the foregoing, 
Subsidiary shall not include any Person in which a Defendant does not 
have majority ownership or de facto control if that Person does not 
provide MVPD service.
    J. ``TWC'' means defendant Time Warner Cable Inc, a New York 
corporation with headquarters in New York, New York, its successors and 
assigns, and its Subsidiaries, divisions, groups, affiliates, 
partnerships and joint ventures, and their directors, officers, 
managers, agents, and employees, in their capacity as directors, 
officers, managers, agents, and employees of the foregoing.
    K. ``Video Programmer'' means any Person that provides Video 
Programming for distribution through MVPDs, in its capacity as a Video 
Programmer.
    L. ``Video Programming'' means programming provided by, or 
generally considered comparable to programming provided by, a 
television broadcast station or cable network, regardless of the medium 
or method used for distribution, and, without expanding the foregoing, 
includes programming prescheduled by the programming provider (also 
known as scheduled programming or a linear feed); programming offered 
to viewers on an on-demand, point-to-point basis (also known as video 
on demand); pay per view or transactional video on demand; short 
programming segments related to other full-length programming (also 
known as clips); programming that includes multiple video sources (also 
known as feeds, including camera angles); programming that includes 
video in different qualities or formats (including high-definition and 
3D); and films for which a year or more has elapsed since their 
theatrical release.

III. APPLICABILITY

    This Final Judgment applies to Defendants and all other Persons in 
active concert or participation with any of them who receive actual 
notice of this Final Judgment by personal service or otherwise.

IV. PROHIBITED CONDUCT AND REPORTING

    A. Defendants shall not enter into or enforce any agreement with a 
Video Programmer under which Defendants forbid, limit, or create 
incentives to limit the Video Programmer's provision of its Video 
Programming to one or more OVDs.
    B. Agreements that ``create incentives to limit'' a Video 
Programmer's provision of its Video Programming to one or more OVDs 
within the meaning of Section IV.A shall include, but are not limited 
to, the following:
    1. agreements that provide for any pecuniary or non-pecuniary 
penalty on the Video Programmer for the provision of its Video 
Programming to an OVD, such as rate reductions, re-tiering or re-
positioning penalties, termination rights for Defendants, or loss or 
waiver of any rights or benefits otherwise available to the Video 
Programmer; or
    2. agreements that entitle Defendants to receive any benefits such 
as favorable rates, contract terms, or content rights offered or 
granted to an OVD by a Video Programmer without requiring Defendants to 
also accept any obligations, limitations, or conditions:
    i. that are integrally related, logically linked, or directly tied 
to the offering or grant of such rights or benefits, and
    ii. with which Defendants can reasonably comply technologically and 
legally. For avoidance of doubt, Defendants will be deemed able to 
``reasonably comply technologically'' if they are able to implement an 
obligation, limitation, or condition in a technologically equivalent 
manner.
    C. Notwithstanding the foregoing, nothing in this Final Judgment 
shall prohibit Defendants from:
    1. entering into and enforcing an agreement under which Defendants 
discourage or prohibit a Video Programmer from making Video Programming 
for which Defendants pay available to consumers for free over the 
Internet within the first 30 days after Defendants first distribute the 
Video Programming to consumers;
    2. entering into and enforcing an agreement under which the Video 
Programmer provides Video Programming exclusively to Defendants, and to 
no other MVPD or OVD; or
    3. entering into and enforcing an agreement which requires that 
Defendants receive as favorable material terms as other MVPDs or OVDs, 
except to the extent application of other MVPDs' or OVDs' terms would 
be inconsistent with the purpose of Sections A and B of this Section 
IV.
    D. Defendants shall not discriminate against, retaliate against, or 
punish any Video Programmer (i) for providing Video Programming to any 
MVPD or OVD, (ii) for invoking any provisions of this Final Judgment, 
(iii) for invoking the provisions of any rules or orders concerning 
Video Programming adopted by the Federal Communications Commission, or 
(iv) for furnishing information to the United States concerning 
Defendants' compliance or noncompliance with this Final Judgment. 
Pursuing a more advantageous deal with a Video Programmer does not 
constitute discrimination, retaliation, or punishment.
    E. Defendants shall submit to the Department of Justice all reports 
and data relating to interconnection with the Defendants' broadband 
Internet access network that are required to be submitted to the 
Federal Communications Commission (``the Commission'') pursuant to any 
rule or order of the Commission, at the same time such reports or data 
are required to be submitted to the Commission.

V. COMPLIANCE INSPECTION

    A. For purposes of determining or securing compliance with this 
Final Judgment, or of determining whether the Final Judgment should be 
modified or vacated, and subject to any legally recognized privilege, 
from time to time duly authorized representatives of the Department of 
Justice, including consultants and other persons retained by the 
Department of Justice, shall, upon written request of an authorized 
representative of the Assistant Attorney General in charge of the 
Antitrust Division, and on reasonable notice to Defendants, be 
permitted:
    1. access during the Defendants' office hours to inspect and copy, 
or at the option of the United States, to require Defendants to provide 
to the United States hard copy or electronic copies of, all books, 
ledgers, accounts, records, data, and documents in the possession, 
custody, or control of Defendants, relating to any matters contained in 
this Final Judgment; and
    2. to interview, either informally or on the record, the 
Defendants' officers, employees, or agents, who may have

[[Page 30565]]

their individual counsel present, regarding such matters. The 
interviews shall be subject to the reasonable convenience of the 
interviewee and without restraint or interference by Defendants.
    B. Upon the written request of an authorized representative of the 
Assistant Attorney General in charge of the Antitrust Division, 
Defendants shall submit written reports or respond to written 
interrogatories, under oath if requested, relating to any of the 
matters contained in this Final Judgment as may be requested.
    C. No information or documents obtained by the means provided in 
this section shall be divulged by the United States to any person other 
than an authorized representative of the executive branch of the United 
States or the Federal Communications Commission, except in the course 
of legal proceedings to which the United States is a party (including 
grand jury proceedings), or for the purpose of securing compliance with 
this Final Judgment, or as otherwise required by law.
    D. If at the time information or documents are furnished by a 
Defendant to the United States, the Defendant represents and identifies 
in writing the material in any such information or documents to which a 
claim of protection may be asserted under Rule 26(c)(1)(G) of the 
Federal Rules of Civil Procedure, and the Defendant marks each 
pertinent page of such material, ``Subject to claim of protection under 
Rule 26(c)(1)(G) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure,'' then the 
United States shall give the Defendant ten calendar days notice prior 
to divulging such material in any civil or administrative proceeding 
(other than a grand jury proceeding).

VI. RETENTION OF JURISDICTION

    This Court retains jurisdiction to enable any party to apply to 
this Court at any time for further orders and directions as may be 
necessary or appropriate to carry out or construe this Final Judgment, 
to modify any of its provisions, to enforce compliance, and to punish 
violations of its provisions.

VII. NO LIMITATION ON GOVERNMENT RIGHTS

    Nothing in this Final Judgment shall limit the right of the United 
States to investigate and bring actions to prevent or restrain 
violations of the antitrust laws concerning any past, present, or 
future conduct, policy, or practice of the Defendants.

VIII. EXPIRATION OF FINAL JUDGMENT

    This Final Judgment shall expire seven years from the date of its 
entry. Notwithstanding the foregoing, the Defendants may request after 
five years that the Department of Justice examine competitive 
conditions and determine whether the Final Judgment continues to be 
necessary to protect competition. If after examination of competitive 
conditions the Department of Justice in its sole discretion concludes 
that the Final Judgment should be terminated, it will recommend to the 
Court that the Final Judgment be terminated.

IX. PUBLIC INTEREST DETERMINATION

    Entry of this Final Judgment is in the public interest. The parties 
have complied with the requirements of the Antitrust Procedures and 
Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16, including making copies available to the 
public of this Final Judgment, the Competitive Impact Statement, and 
any comments thereon and the United States' responses to comments. 
Based upon the record before the Court, which includes the Competitive 
Impact Statement and any comments and response to comments filed with 
the Court, entry of this Final Judgment is in the public interest.

Date:------------------------------------------------------------------

Court approval subject to procedures set forth in the Antitrust 
Procedures and Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16

-----------------------------------------------------------------------
United States District Judge

[FR Doc. 2016-11562 Filed 5-16-16; 8:45 am]
 BILLING CODE 4410-11-P


Current View
CategoryRegulatory Information
CollectionFederal Register
sudoc ClassAE 2.7:
GS 4.107:
AE 2.106:
PublisherOffice of the Federal Register, National Archives and Records Administration
SectionNotices
FR Citation81 FR 30550 

2024 Federal Register | Disclaimer | Privacy Policy
USC | CFR | eCFR