81 FR 74842 - Self-Regulatory Organizations; NYSE MKT LLC; Order Disapproving a Proposed Rule Change To Modify the NYSE Amex Options Fee Schedule With Respect to Fees, Rebates, and Credits for Transactions in the Customer Best Execution Auction

SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION

Federal Register Volume 81, Issue 208 (October 27, 2016)

Page Range74842-74847
FR Document2016-25941

Federal Register, Volume 81 Issue 208 (Thursday, October 27, 2016)
[Federal Register Volume 81, Number 208 (Thursday, October 27, 2016)]
[Notices]
[Pages 74842-74847]
From the Federal Register Online  [www.thefederalregister.org]
[FR Doc No: 2016-25941]


-----------------------------------------------------------------------

SECURITIES AND EXCHANGE COMMISSION

[Release No. 34-79135; File No. SR-NYSEMKT-2016-45]


Self-Regulatory Organizations; NYSE MKT LLC; Order Disapproving a 
Proposed Rule Change To Modify the NYSE Amex Options Fee Schedule With 
Respect to Fees, Rebates, and Credits for Transactions in the Customer 
Best Execution Auction

October 21, 2016.

I. Introduction

    On April 11, 2016, NYSE MKT LLC (the ``Exchange'' or ``NYSE MKT'') 
filed with the Securities and Exchange Commission (the ``Commission''), 
pursuant to Section 19(b)(1) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 
(the ``Act''),\1\ and Rule 19b-4 thereunder,\2\ a proposed rule change 
(File No. SR-NYSEMKT-2016-45) to modify the

[[Page 74843]]

NYSE Amex Options Fee Schedule with respect to fees, rebates, and 
credits relating to the Exchange's Customer Best Execution Auction 
(``CUBE Auction''),\3\ and to increase credits available under the 
Exchange's Amex Customer Engagement Program (``ACE Program'').\4\ The 
proposed rule change was immediately effective upon filing with the 
Commission pursuant to Section 19(b)(3)(A) of the Act.\5\ Notice of 
filing of the proposed rule change was published in the Federal 
Register on April 26, 2016.\6\ On June 9, 2016, the Commission 
temporarily suspended the Exchange's proposal and simultaneously 
instituted proceedings to determine whether to approve or disapprove 
the proposed rule change.\7\ The Commission thereafter received ten 
comment letters on the proposal, one of which was from the Exchange.\8\ 
This order disapproves the proposed rule change.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \1\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(1).
    \2\ 17 CFR 240.19b-4.
    \3\ The CUBE Auction is a mechanism in which an Exchange ATP 
Holder submits an agency order on behalf of a customer for price 
improvement, paired with a contra-side order guaranteeing execution 
of the agency order at or better than the National Best Bid or Offer 
(``NBBO'') depending on the circumstances. The contra-side order 
could be for the account of the ATP Holder that initiated the CUBE 
Auction (``Initiating Participant''), or an order solicited from 
another participant. The agency order is exposed for a random period 
of time between 500 and 750 milliseconds in which other ATP Holders 
submit competing interest at the same price as the initial price or 
better (``RFR Responses''). The Initiating Participant is guaranteed 
at least 40% of any remainder of the order (after public customers 
and better-priced RFR Responses) at the final price for the CUBE 
order. See NYSE MKT Rule 971.1NY.
    \4\ Under the ACE Program, credits are available to ATP Holders 
that bring customer orders to the Exchange based on the percentage 
(by tier) of national industry customer volume those customer orders 
comprise. See NYSE Amex Options Fee Schedule Section I.E.
    \5\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(3)(A).
    \6\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 77658 (April 20, 
2016), 81 FR 24674 (``Notice'').
    \7\ See Securities Exchange Act Release No. 78029, 81 FR 39089 
(June 15, 2016) (``Order Instituting Proceedings'').
    \8\ See Letters to Brent J. Fields, Secretary, Commission, from 
John C. Nagel, Managing Director and Sr. Deputy General Counsel, 
Citadel LLC, dated July 6, 2016 (``Citadel Letter''); Elizabeth K. 
King, General Counsel and Corporate Secretary, New York Stock 
Exchange, dated July 8, 2016 (``NYSE MKT Letter''); Eric Chern, 
Chief Executive Officer, CTC Trading Group, L.L.C., dated July 28, 
2016 (``CTC Letter''); Sebastiaan Koeling, Chief Executive Officer, 
Optiver US LLC, dated August 3, 2016 (``Optiver Letter''); Gerald D. 
O'Connell, Susquehanna International Group, Andrew Stevens, IMC 
Financial Markets LLC, Edward Haravon, Spot Trading, Kurt Eckert, 
Wolverine Trading and Peter Schwarz, Integral Derivatives, dated 
August 5, 2016 (``Options Market Maker Firms Letter''); John 
Kinahan, Chief Executive Officer, Group One Trading, L.P., dated 
August 8, 2016 (``Group One Letter''); Joanna Mallers, Secretary, 
FIA Principal Traders Group, dated August 10, 2016 (``FIA PTG 
Letter''); John Russell, Chairman of the Board and James Toes, 
President and CEO, Security Traders Association, dated August 29, 
2016 (``STA Letter''); and John A. McCarthy, General Counsel, KCG 
Holdings, Inc., dated September 16, 2016 (``KCG Letter''); and 
Letter to Robert W. Errett, Deputy Secretary, Commission, from Ellen 
Greene, Managing Director, Securities Industry and Financial Markets 
Association, dated July 12, 2016 (``SIFMA Letter'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

II. Description of the Proposed Rule Change

    The Exchange's proposal amended certain fees, rebates, and credits 
relating to executions through its CUBE Auction. First, the proposal 
increased the fees assessed by the Exchange for RFR Responses (i.e., 
orders and quotes submitted during a CUBE Auction that are executed 
against the agency order).\9\ Specifically, the Exchange increased RFR 
Response fees for Non-Customers (including market makers) from $0.12 to 
$0.70 for classes subject to the Penny Pilot \10\ (``Penny classes'') 
and from $0.12 to $1.05 for classes not subject to the Penny Pilot 
(``Non-Penny classes'').
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \9\ See supra note 3 and NYSE Amex Options Fee Schedule, Section 
I.G.
    \10\ See Commentary .02 to NYSE MKT Rule 960NY. See also 
Securities Exchange Act Release No. 75281 (June 24, 2015), 80 FR 
37338 (June 30, 2015) (SR-NYSEMKT-2015-43) (extending the Penny 
Pilot through June 30, 2016).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    Further, the proposal increased a rebate available to Initiating 
Participants in CUBE Auctions (i.e., ATP Holders that initiate such 
auctions) \11\ under the Exchange's ACE Program. Specifically, the 
proposal increased the rebate paid to Initiating Participants that meet 
certain tiers of the ACE Program from $0.05 to $0.18 (the ``ACE 
Initiating Participant Rebate'') for each of the first 5,000 Customer 
contracts of an agency order executed in a CUBE Auction.\12\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \11\ See supra note 3.
    \12\ See NYSE Amex Options Fee Schedule, Section I.G.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    Finally, the proposal increased the credit paid by the Exchange to 
Initiating Participants (the ``break-up credit'') for each contract in 
the contra-side order that is paired with the agency order that does 
not trade with the agency order because it is replaced in the auction. 
Prior to the proposal, the credit granted was $0.05 per contract in all 
classes. The proposal raised it to $0.35 for Penny classes and $0.70 
for Non-Penny classes.\13\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \13\ See id. In addition to its proposed changes to CUBE Auction 
fees and credits, the Exchange's proposal also increased certain 
credits available through its ACE Program with respect to non-CUBE 
transactions. See Notice, supra note 6, at 24674-75. See also NYSE 
Amex Options Fee Schedule, Section I.E.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    The amended fees resulted in a proposed difference between the fees 
charged to an Initiating Participant and those charged to Non-Customer 
auction responders that would be a minimum of $0.65 in Penny classes 
and $1.00 in Non-Penny classes.\14\ Taking into consideration that the 
ACE rebate available to an Initiating Participant submitting the agency 
order into the CUBE Auction was increased to $0.18, this proposed fee 
differential could be as high as $0.83 per executed contract for Penny 
classes, and $1.18 per contract for Non-Penny classes.\15\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \14\ See Order Instituting Proceedings, supra note 7, at 39090 
n.20.
    \15\ See id. at 39091.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    In its filing, the Exchange stated that the changes to the CUBE 
Auction transaction fees are reasonable, equitable and not unfairly 
discriminatory ``because they apply equally to all ATP Holders that 
choose to participate in the CUBE, and access to the Exchange is 
offered on terms that are not unfairly discriminatory.'' \16\ The 
Exchange also took the position, with regard specifically to the ACE 
Initiating Participant Credit, that the change is reasonable, 
equitable, and not unfairly discriminatory because it is ``designed to 
attract more volume and liquidity to the Exchange generally, and to 
CUBE Auctions specifically,'' which, according to the Exchange, ``would 
benefit all market participants . . . through increased opportunities 
to trade at potentially improved prices as well as enhancing price 
discovery.'' \17\ The Exchange stated that its proposal is reasonable 
because it is similar to the fee and credit structures previously 
applied to the CUBE Auction and to fees charged for similar auctions on 
other exchanges.\18\ The Exchange further stated that the proposal 
``would improve the Exchange's overall competitiveness and strengthen 
its market quality for all market participants.'' \19\ Finally, the 
Exchange stated that it did not believe the proposal would impose any 
unnecessary or inappropriate burden on competition because it is ``pro-
competitive'' and ``designed to incent increases in the number of CUBE 
Auctions brought to the Exchange,'' thereby ``benefit[ting] all 
Exchange participants through increased opportunities to trade as well 
as enhancing price discovery.'' \20\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \16\ See Notice, supra note 6, at 24675.
    \17\ See id. at 24675-76.
    \18\ See id. at 24675 & n.10.
    \19\ See id. at 24676. The Exchange stated that the CUBE fee and 
credit adjustments established by the instant proposal are 
consistent with the fees and credits that were in place for the same 
items in its Fee Schedule prior to February 2016. See id. at 24675 
n.6.
    \20\ See id. at 24676. The Exchange also noted that it operates 
in a highly-competitive market. See id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 74844]]

III. Order Instituting Proceedings and Comments Received

    In the Order Instituting Proceedings, the Commission stated that it 
would further assess whether the proposal satisfies the statutory 
provisions that require exchange rules to: (1) provide for the 
equitable allocation of reasonable fees among members, issuers, and 
other persons using its facilities; \21\ (2) be designed to perfect the 
mechanism of a free and open market and a national market system and to 
protect investors and the public interest, and not be designed to 
permit unfair discrimination between customers, issuers, brokers, or 
dealers; \22\ and (3) not impose any burden on competition not 
necessary or appropriate in furtherance of the purposes of the Act.\23\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \21\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4).
    \22\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(5).
    \23\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(8).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    In the Order Instituting Proceedings, the Commission expressed 
concern about the potential effect the proposal could have on the 
operation of the CUBE Auction and its potential to provide price 
improvement to customers, as well as about its effect upon competition 
among participants initiating CUBE Auctions and those responding to 
them.\24\ The Commission acknowledged that increasing the rebates and 
break-up credits provided to Initiating Participants likely would 
strengthen their incentive to bring customer orders to the 
Exchange.\25\ However, the Commission also noted that substantially 
increasing the fees paid by Non-Customer auction responders could deter 
them from participating in CUBE Auctions.\26\ The Commission observed 
that in Penny classes, for example, the fee charged Non-Customer 
auction responders would exceed one-half the minimum trading increment, 
and the economic differential between such auction responders and the 
Initiating Participants with whom they are competing would be even 
more.\27\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \24\ See Order Instituting Proceedings, supra note 7, at 39090.
    \25\ See id. at 39091.
    \26\ See id.
    \27\ See id. See also supra text accompanying notes 14 and 15.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    Further, in the Order Instituting Proceedings, the Commission 
raised questions as to whether the proposal would in fact provide the 
additional trading opportunities for Non-Customer auction responders 
and other market quality benefits suggested by the Exchange.\28\ The 
Commission noted that the Exchange did not address the fact that the 
proposal would substantially increase the difference in the fees 
assessed by the Exchange on Initiating Participants and Non-Customer 
auction responders, and indicated that substantially exacerbating the 
differences in the fees assessed by the Exchange on Initiating 
Participants and those assessed on Non-Customer auction responders 
raises issues as to whether the proposal is equitable and not unfairly 
discriminatory among Exchange members.\29\ The Commission also noted in 
the Order Instituting Proceedings that the Exchange did not support 
with specific reasoning or data its statement that the proposal would 
provide all members additional trading opportunities and other market 
quality benefits. The Commission further stated that the Exchange did 
not sufficiently address the potential burden that its proposed fee 
changes would have on competition between Initiating Participants and 
Non-Customer auction responders, or the prospect that competition in 
CUBE Auctions could be impaired, by substantially increasing the 
auction response fees paid by Non-Customer auction responders. 
Moreover, the Commission noted that the Exchange did not address in any 
detail the increases in the break-up credit payable to an Initiating 
Participant for each contract in a CUBE Order that is executed by 
others, and why the proposed increase in this payment is reasonable, 
equitable, and not unfairly discriminatory.\30\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \28\ See Order Instituting Proceedings, supra note 7, at 39090.
    \29\ See id. at 39091.
    \30\ See id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    The Commission received ten comment letters in response to the 
Order Instituting Proceedings, one of which was from the Exchange.\31\ 
The nine commenters other than the Exchange either specifically 
recommended that the Commission disapprove the Exchange's proposal or 
expressed concerns about the proposal in its current form.\32\ Broadly, 
these commenters echoed many of the concerns, summarized above, that 
were raised by the Commission in the Order Instituting Proceedings. 
Among other things, commenters focused on the potential impact of the 
proposed raising of fees for Non-Customer auction responders, increases 
in rebates to Initiating Participants, and heightened differential in 
the costs between Non-Customer auction responders and Initiating 
Participants, that would result from the proposal. They also questioned 
the level of auction response fees generally, the consequences of 
break-up credits, and the potential effect of the proposal on the 
quoting behavior of market makers.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \31\ See supra note 8.
    \32\ See SIFMA Letter; FIA PTG Letter; Options Market Maker 
Firms Letter; Optiver Letter; Group One Letter; STA Letter; CTC 
Letter; Citadel Letter; KCG Letter.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    More specifically, many commenters believed that the fee 
differentials created by the Exchange's proposal would significantly 
favor Initiating Participants over Non-Customer auction responders.\33\ 
Some commenters highlighted the fact that the proposed increase in fees 
assessed on Non-Customer auction responders, without any change to the 
Initiating Participant fees, would widen the differential between these 
two groups of participants.\34\ Several commenters acknowledged that 
the Exchange's auction fee structure was not unique in providing for 
differentials, but emphasized their belief that the Exchange's proposal 
would further and unacceptably exacerbate a trend of raising auction 
response fees and widening differentials.\35\ To the extent that the 
proposal would further increase these fees and widen the disparity in 
fees assessed on the different participants, these commenters believed 
that the proposal was inequitable, unfairly discriminatory, and 
unreasonably burdensome on competition.\36\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \33\ See, e.g., Citadel Letter at 2-3; CTC Letter at 2-4; Group 
One Letter at 2; Options Market Maker Firms Letter at 3; Optiver 
Letter at 2; KCG Letter at 2, 6.
    \34\ See Citadel Letter at 2; KCG Letter at 2.
    \35\ See, e.g., Citadel Letter at 2-3 (stating that the 
Exchange's proposal would ``significantly'' increase the difference 
in net cost to Non-Customer auction responders as compared to 
Initiating Participants and would be ``starkly discriminatory''); 
Options Market Maker Firms Letter at 3-5; 8 (arguing that the fee 
differential for participating in CUBE is ``so punitive that [Non-
Customer auction responders] cannot compete on price at anywhere 
near equal terms with [Initiating Participants]'' and objecting to 
fee differentials that would be ``significantly higher'' than any 
other options exchange auction); Optiver Letter at 2, 4 (noting a 
``gross disparity in fees'' between Non-Customer auction responders 
and Initiating Participants under the proposal and finding such 
disparity to be the highest among competing exchanges). See also STA 
Letter at 1 (suggesting that the Exchange be permitted to adopt fees 
``more aligned with other exchanges'').
    \36\ See id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    A few commenters stated that an effect of the proposed fees would 
be to limit opportunities for price improvement in the CUBE mechanism 
by discouraging auction responders from effectively participating.\37\ 
One of these commenters further argued that the diminished competition 
would encourage Initiating Participants to submit less competitive 
prices to begin an auction.\38\ Two commenters took the

[[Page 74845]]

position that it was unfairly discriminatory to increase fees for Non-
Customer auction responders while correspondingly increasing rebates to 
Initiating Participants.\39\ One of these commenters further suggested 
that the Commission impose a maximum fee differential of $0.02 between 
Initiating Participants and non-Initiating Participants.\40\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \37\ See, e.g., Citadel Letter at 2-3; CTC Letter at 4; Group 
One Letter at 2.
    \38\ See Group One Letter at 2.
    \39\ See CTC Letter at 2-4; KCG Letter at 2, 5-6.
    \40\ See CTC Letter at 2-4 (comparing this proposed limitation 
to transaction fee differentials between directed and unaffiliated 
market makers trading against a directed order).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    Commenters expressed other concerns as well. One commenter stated 
that high response fees generally disincentivize firms from responding 
to an auction and offering price improvement.\41\ Another commenter 
argued that auction response fees are comparable to access fees charged 
by exchanges and should be limited more generally.\42\ Two commenters 
supported limiting auction response fees in both Penny and Non-Penny 
classes to no more than half the minimum trading increment.\43\ Another 
commenter similarly supported a cap on auction response fees, but 
stated that the amount should be set at a much lower level than half 
the minimum increment in the Penny classes.\44\ Still another commenter 
stated that an absolute cap would not be necessary.\45\ Instead, this 
commenter maintained, the Commission should prohibit fee differentials 
between market participants, reasoning that, if exchanges were barred 
from discriminating between participant types, competitive market 
forces would lower the absolute fee levels to a reasonable amount.\46\ 
In addition, five commenters expressed specific concern about break-up 
credits,\47\ contending that they are per se unfairly discriminatory in 
that they provide a benefit solely to Initiating Participants and 
thereby discourage competition and limit price improvement.\48\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \41\ See SIFMA Letter at 2.
    \42\ See Citadel Letter at 4.
    \43\ See Citadel Letter at 7; CTC Letter at 3. Citadel supported 
limiting all transaction fees in Penny classes at $0.50, and stated 
that the minimum increment considered in setting auction fees should 
be the minimum increment of an auction response. Citadel Letter at 
7. CTC stated that auction response fees should be limited at $0.50 
for all series because all price improvement auctions allow 
responses in penny increments. CTC Letter at 3.
    \44\ See Options Market Maker Firms Letter at 9.
    \45\ See Optiver Letter at 5.
    \46\ Id. This commenter believes that, absent discriminatory 
fees, competition would lead to an amount that was much lower than 
half the minimum trading increment. Id. The commenter further stated 
that even if an absolute response fee limitation were to be imposed, 
an exchange could offer rebates sufficiently high to maintain a 
large differential in fees between market participants. Id.
    \47\ See supra text accompanying note 13.
    \48\ See CTC Letter at 4; Options Market Maker Firms Letter at 
4; Optiver Letter at 3; Group One Trading Letter at 2-3; STA Letter 
at 2-3.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    Several commenters expressed concern that high transaction fees in 
auction mechanisms generally, not only the fees under the Exchange's 
proposal, could harm options market quality by negatively impacting 
market maker quoting behavior.\49\ A few commenters believed that high 
auction response fees, such as those proposed by the Exchange, would 
discourage quoting in the options markets because they would encourage 
increased internalization in the auctions.\50\ One of these commenters 
stated that market makers would respond to the proposed fees by 
reducing the number, size, and quality of their displayed 
quotations.\51\ Another commenter believed that this would diminish the 
degree of actual price improvement provided by the auctions, because, 
while auction executions will occur at or better than the NBBO, this 
NBBO may have been better at the outset if not for the negative effects 
of the high auction fees.\52\ One commenter contended that increased 
transaction fees in general, and especially disproportionate fees among 
various market participants, will lead to overall decreased competition 
and liquidity in the options market.\53\ In addition, several 
commenters expressed concerns that break-up fees, break-up credits, 
auto-match functionality, and the ability to initiate an auction at the 
NBBO are all among features of auctions that may incentivize 
internalization, decrease competition, and impair market quality.\54\ 
Finally, commenters broadly suggested that the Commission conduct a 
holistic review of options exchange electronic auction mechanisms.\55\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \49\ See, e.g., Citadel Letter at 6; FIA PTG Letter at 1; NYSE 
MKT Letter at 2; Options Market Maker Firms Letter at 2-3, 6; SIFMA 
Letter at 2; KCG Letter at 2.
    \50\ See, e.g., Citadel Letter at 6; Options Market Maker Firms 
Letter at 6; SIFMA Letter at 2. In response, the Exchange 
acknowledged that price improvement auctions encourage 
internalization to the detriment of displayed market maker 
quotations, but argued that this was the result of a lack of 
guaranteed price improvement in most exchanges' auctions. See NYSE 
MKT Letter at 2.
    \51\ See Citadel Letter at 6.
    \52\ See Options Market Maker Firms Letter at 2-3.
    \53\ See FIA PTG Letter at 1.
    \54\ See, e.g., FIA PTG Letter at 2, Options Market Maker Firms 
Letter at 3, CTC Letter at 3.
    \55\ See Citadel Letter at 7; CTC Letter at 1; FIA PTG Letter at 
2; Group One Trading Letter at 1, 3; NYSE MKT Letter at 4-5; Options 
Market Maker Firms Letter at 2; Optiver Letter at 1, 4; SIFMA Letter 
at 3; STA Letter at 3; KCG Letter at 5-6. The Commission notes that 
while the Exchange supported such a review in its letter, the 
Exchange requested that the Commission end the suspension of the 
instant filing while undertaking this review. See NYSE MKT Letter at 
5.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    In its comment letter, the Exchange broadly expressed concerns with 
options exchange electronic auction mechanisms, and stated its belief 
that such mechanisms should guarantee price improvement.\56\ However, 
the Exchange did not provide additional justification for the proposal, 
or respond specifically to the concerns expressed in the Order 
Instituting Proceedings. Rather, the Exchange stated that its proposal 
was developed in response to competitive concerns and that the 
suspension placed it at a competitive disadvantage compared to other 
exchanges with comparable fees that were unaffected by the Order 
Instituting Proceedings.\57\ The Exchange requested that the Commission 
end its temporary suspension of the proposal while the Commission 
undertakes a broad review of the fee structures applied by the options 
exchanges to their price improvement auctions.\58\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \56\ See NYSE MKT Letter at 4.
    \57\ See id. at 3-4 In particular, the Exchange stated that it 
was aware of two other options exchanges that, like the Exchange, 
were charging auction response fees in Penny classes of more than 
$0.50 per contract. See id. at 4.
    \58\ See id. at 1, 4.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

IV. Discussion and Commission Findings

    Under Section 19(b)(2)(C) of the Act,\59\ the Commission shall 
approve a proposed rule change of a self-regulatory organization if it 
finds that such proposed rule change is consistent with the 
requirements of the Act and the rules and regulations thereunder that 
are applicable to such organization.\60\ The Commission shall 
disapprove a proposed rule change if it does not make such a 
finding.\61\ Rule 700(b)(3) of the Commission's Rules of Practice 
states that the ``burden to demonstrate that a proposed rule change is 
consistent with the Exchange Act and the rules and regulations issued 
thereunder . . . is on the self-regulatory organization that proposed 
the rule change'' and that a ``mere assertion that the proposed rule 
change is consistent with those requirements . . . is not sufficient.'' 
\62\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \59\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(2)(C).
    \60\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(2)(C)(i).
    \61\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(2)(C)(ii); see also 17 CFR 201.700(b)(3).
    \62\ 17 CFR 201.700(b)(3). The description of a proposed rule 
change, its purpose and operation, its effect, and a legal analysis 
of its consistency with applicable requirements must all be 
sufficiently detailed and specific to support an affirmative 
Commission finding. See id. Any failure of a self-regulatory 
organization to provide the information elicited by Form 19b-4 may 
result in the Commission not having a sufficient basis to make an 
affirmative finding that a proposed rule change is consistent with 
the Exchange Act and the rules and regulations issued thereunder 
that are applicable to the self-regulatory organization. Id.

---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[[Page 74846]]

    In the Order Instituting Proceedings, the Commission raised 
concerns about the effect the proposal could have on the operation of 
the CUBE Auction and its ability to provide price improvement to 
customers, as well as the impact it could have on competition among 
participants initiating CUBE Auctions and those responding to them.\63\ 
The Commission pointed to several specific elements of the proposal for 
which, in its view, the Exchange had not provided sufficient 
justification to enable the Commission to find that the proposal was 
consistent with the Act.\64\ In particular, the Commission noted that 
the Exchange justified the proposal on the grounds that it would create 
incentives for Initiating Participants to bring customer orders to the 
Exchange, and thereby benefit all members by providing more trading 
opportunities, potential price improvement, tighter spreads, and 
enhanced market quality.\65\ The Commission acknowledged that 
increasing the rebates and break-up credits provided to Initiating 
Participants likely would strengthen their incentives to bring customer 
orders to the Exchange, but expressed concern that substantially 
increasing the fees paid by Non-Customer auction responders could deter 
them from participating in CUBE Auctions.\66\ The Commission further 
noted that the proposal would substantially exacerbate the differences 
in the fees assessed by the Exchange on Non-Customer auction responders 
as compared to those for Initiating Participants.\67\ The Commission 
stated that in Penny classes, for example, the fee charged Non-Customer 
auction responders would exceed one-half the minimum trading increment, 
and the economic differential between Non-Customer auction responders 
and the Initiating Participants with whom they are competing would be 
even more.\68\ Accordingly, the Commission believed that questions were 
raised as to whether the proposal would in fact provide the additional 
trading opportunities for non-Initiating Participants and other market 
quality benefits suggested by the Exchange.\69\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \63\ See Order Instituting Proceedings, supra note 7, at 39090.
    \64\ See id.
    \65\ See id. at 39091.
    \66\ See id.
    \67\ See id.
    \68\ See id.
    \69\ See id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    As discussed above, most commenters broadly echoed the Commission's 
concerns, and several expressed the view that the proposal would not 
provide the additional trading opportunities for non-Initiating 
Participants and other market quality benefits suggested by the 
Exchange. Specifically, several commenters stated that an effect of the 
proposed fees would be to limit opportunities for price improvement in 
the CUBE mechanism by discouraging auction responders from effectively 
participating,\70\ and expressed concern that the fee structure in 
auction mechanisms could harm options market quality by negatively 
impacting market maker quoting behavior.\71\ In addition, commenters 
were concerned that the proposed fees would widen the cost differential 
between Non-Customer auction responders and Initiating Participants 
such that the differential would be excessive as compared with those of 
other options exchanges.\72\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \70\ See supra note 37.
    \71\ See supra notes 50-52 and accompanying text.
    \72\ See supra notes 33-36 and accompanying text.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    In its comment letter, the Exchange did not respond specifically to 
the concerns articulated in the Order Instituting Proceedings or in the 
comments, or otherwise offer any additional information to support its 
view that the proposal would provide additional trading opportunities 
for non-Initiating Participants and other market quality benefits.\73\ 
The Exchange simply characterized its proposal as a competitive 
response to certain other options exchanges, two of which had been 
charging auction response fees in Penny classes in excess of $0.50 per 
contract. The Commission notes that, in the interim, both such 
exchanges have reduced their auction response fees (inclusive of 
marketing fees) so that they no longer exceed half the minimum trading 
increment in Penny classes.\74\
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \73\ In particular, the Exchange did not address the fact that 
the proposal would substantially increase the difference in the fees 
assessed by the Exchange on Initiating Participants and Non-Customer 
auction responders; did not support with specific reasoning or data 
its statement that the proposal would provide all members additional 
trading opportunities and other market quality benefits; did not 
sufficiently address the potential burden that its proposed fee 
changes would have on competition between Initiating Participants 
and Non-Customer auction responders, or the prospect that, by 
substantially increasing the auction response fees paid by Non-
Customer auction responders, competition in CUBE Auctions could be 
impaired; and did not address in any detail the increases in the 
break-up credit payable to Initiating Participants for each contract 
that they are not able to execute in CUBE, and why this payment is 
reasonable, equitable, and not unfairly discriminatory.
    \74\ See Securities Exchange Act Release Nos. 78117 (June 21, 
2016), 81 FR 41634 (June 27, 2016) (SR-NYSEMKT-2016-60); 78394 (July 
22, 2016), 81 FR 49709 (July 28, 2016) (SR-Phlx-2016-77); 78427 
(July 27, 2016), 81 FR 50777 (August 2, 2016) (SR-BOX-2016-34).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    As noted, Rule 700(b)(3) of the Commission's Rules of Practice 
states that the ``burden to demonstrate that a proposed rule change is 
consistent with the Exchange Act and the rules and regulations issued 
thereunder . . . is on the self-regulatory organization that proposed 
the rule change'' and that a ``mere assertion that the proposed rule 
change is consistent with those requirements . . . is not sufficient.'' 
\75\ The Exchange has taken the position that its proposal meets 
applicable Exchange Act standards, including that fees be reasonable, 
equitably allocated, and not unfairly discriminatory, and that they not 
impose any unnecessary or inappropriate burden on competition, on the 
grounds that the proposed fee changes would benefit all market 
participants through increased trading opportunities and improved 
market quality. Although the Commission expressed concern, in the Order 
Instituting Proceedings, that the reasoning behind this assertion was 
not clear and no supporting data had been provided, the Exchange has 
offered no additional justification or evidence to support this key 
aspect of its statutory basis.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \75\ 17 CFR 201.700(b)(3). The description of a proposed rule 
change, its purpose and operation, its effect, and a legal analysis 
of its consistency with applicable requirements must all be 
sufficiently detailed and specific to support an affirmative 
Commission finding. See id. Any failure of a self-regulatory 
organization to provide the information elicited by Form 19b-4 may 
result in the Commission not having a sufficient basis to make an 
affirmative finding that a proposed rule change is consistent with 
the Exchange Act and the rules and regulations issued thereunder 
that are applicable to the self-regulatory organization. Id.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    Accordingly, after careful consideration, the Commission does not 
find that the proposed rule change is consistent with the requirements 
of the Act and the rules and regulations thereunder applicable to a 
national securities exchange.\76\ In particular, the Commission does 
not find that the proposed rule change is consistent with: (1) Section 
6(b)(4) of the Act,\77\ which requires that the rules of a national 
securities exchange provide for the equitable allocation of reasonable 
dues, fees, and other charges among its members and issuers and other 
persons

[[Page 74847]]

using its facilities; (2) Section 6(b)(5) of the Act,\78\ which 
requires that the rules of a national securities exchange be designed, 
among other things, to prevent fraudulent and manipulative acts and 
practices, to promote just and equitable principles of trade, to remove 
impediments to and perfect the mechanism of a free and open market and 
a national market system, and, in general, to protect investors and the 
public interest, and not be designed to permit unfair discrimination 
between customers, issuers, brokers, or dealers; and (3) Section 
6(b)(8) of the Act,\79\ which requires that the rules of a national 
securities exchange do not impose any burden on competition not 
necessary or appropriate in furtherance of the purposes of the Act. 
Because any of these determinations under the Act independently 
necessitates disapproving the proposal, the Commission does so.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \76\ In disapproving the proposed rule change, the Commission 
has considered the proposed rule's impact on efficiency, 
competition, and capital formation. See 15 U.S.C. 78c(f).
    \77\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(4).
    \78\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(5).
    \79\ 15 U.S.C. 78f(b)(8).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

V. Conclusion

    For the reasons set forth above, the Commission does not find that 
the proposed rule change is consistent with the Act and the rules and 
regulations thereunder applicable to a national securities exchange, 
and in particular, Sections 6(b)(4), 6(b)(5), and 6(b)(8) of the Act.
    It is therefore ordered, pursuant to Section 19(b)(2) of the 
Act,\80\ that the proposed rule change (SR-NYSEMKT-2016-45) be, and 
hereby is, disapproved.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \80\ 15 U.S.C. 78s(b)(2).

    For the Commission, by the Division of Trading and Markets, 
pursuant to delegated authority.\81\
Brent J. Fields,
Secretary.
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \81\ 17 CFR 200.30-3(a)(57) and (58).
---------------------------------------------------------------------------

[FR Doc. 2016-25941 Filed 10-26-16; 8:45 am]
 BILLING CODE 8011-01-P


Current View
CategoryRegulatory Information
CollectionFederal Register
sudoc ClassAE 2.7:
GS 4.107:
AE 2.106:
PublisherOffice of the Federal Register, National Archives and Records Administration
SectionNotices
FR Citation81 FR 74842 

2024 Federal Register | Disclaimer | Privacy Policy
USC | CFR | eCFR